петък, 22 януари 2010 г.


Бъфет критикува сделката между Kraft и Cadbury

12:28 | 21.01.2010


Уорън Бъфет, чиито Berkshire Hathaway Inc. е най- големият акционер в Kraft Foods Inc., заяви, че производителят на бисквитите Oreo в платил прекалено висока цена, за да получи Cadbury PLC, съобщава The Wall Street Journal.
Пред CNBC Бъфет подкрепи изпълнителния директор на Kraft Ирене Розенфелд, но допълни, че „има много съмнения около сделката. Ако имам възможност да гласувам, бих дал отрицателен глас.”
Коментарите на Бъфет идват ден след като управителния борд на Cadbury препоръча на акционерите на британската компания да приемат оферта на Kraft Foods след като последната предложи $19.1 млрд. или 850 цента за акция, като първоначално предлагаше 745 цента. Около 60 % от офертата ще бъде платена в брой, останалата в акции на Kraft.
„Уважаваме мнението на Бъфет,” заяви говорителят на Kraft. „На мнение сме, обаче, че сделката е добра за нас. Тя ще обогати портфолиото ни и ще осигури дългосрочен ръст.”
На въпрос дали планира да продаде приблизително 10 -процентното си участие, Бъфет отговори, че „това е прекалено скъп ход” и добави, че „дори да не одобрява управлението, не означава, че би напуснал страната.”
22 януари 2010
Бъфет: Шефовете на фалирали банки да бъдат лишавани от имуществото
INSURANCE.BG
запиши отпечатай изпрати на приятел



Стенли О’Нийл, под ръководството на когото Merrill Lynch отписа активи за $55,9 млрд., беше уволнен в края на 2007 г. с обезщетение в размер на $160 млн


За фалит на банка изпълнителният й директор трябва да бъде отговорен с целия размер на имуществото си и дори имуществото на съпругата си, смята легендарният инвеститор Уорън Бъфет. Президентът Абама трябва да включи подобно изискване в пакета реформи на банковия сектор, е заявил Бъфет в интервю за „Фокс бизнес нетуърк“.
„Трябва да се направи така, че изпълнителният директор на компания, която е рухнала или е преминала под контрола на държавата трябва да бъде унищожен от финансова гледна точка. Защо той трябва да се чувства по-добре от работника, уволнен от General Motors?“, е заявил Бъфет.
Всеки изпълнителен директор трябва да действа като директор по риска. Самият Бъфет вече много години получава годишна заплата в размер на $100 хил. Допълнително той не получава никакви бонуси. В същото време далеч не всички ръководители на банки, пострадали в резултат на кризата понесоха финансови загуби.
Например Стенли О’Нийл, под ръководството на когото Merrill Lynch отписа активи за $55,9 млрд., беше уволнен в края на 2007 г. с обезщетение в размер на $160 млн.
Изпълнителният директор на спасената от крах с парите на държавата британска Royal Bank of Scotland Фред Гудуин напусна с ежегодна пенсия в размер на 693 000 паунда ($1,13 млн.).
22 януари 2010
Goldman Sachs оряза годишните бонуси с $3 млрд.
INSURANCE.BG




Във вид на премии ще бъдат раздадени 35,8% от чистата печалба или $16,19 млрд., което е най-малката сума, отделена за премии, откакто Goldman Sachs е публично дружество


Американската банка Goldman Sachs съобщи, че е "проявила сдържаност", съкращавайки бонусите на служителите си, макар че средната работна заплата в компанията от $498 хил. е достатъчен мотив, за да предизвика негодувание в политическите и синдикалните кръгове, коментира АП.

Goldman съкрати общия размер на бонусите с $3 млрд. - до $16,19 млрд.

Това представлява 35,8% от чистата печалба на дружеството, но е най-малката сума, отделена за премии, откакто Goldman Sachs започна да се търгува на борсата през 1999 г.

Финансовият директор на банката Дейвид Виняр е заявил, че компанията не затваря очите си пред икономическата ситуация, и се е вслушала в призивите за сдържаност.

Решението за свиване на бонусите позволи на компанията да отчете по-голяма печалба за четвъртото тримесечие на миналата година - $4,95 млрд. или $8,20 на акция. Годишната печалба достигна $13,39 млрд.

Средствата, които няма да бъдат изразходвани за бонуси ще бъдат разпределени между акционерите.

Виняр е подчертал, че не високите бонуси, а лошото управление на рисковете е станало причина за краха през последните години.

В резултат на всичко това са пострадали не само служителите, но и управляващите компанията.

По думите на Виняр ръководството на банката ще получи премиите си под формата на акции, които обаче няма да могат да бъдат продавани през следващите пет години. 

Служителите ще получат като бонуси акции и пари.

четвъртък, 21 януари 2010 г.

21 януари 2010, четвъртък
21 януари 2010
Уорън Бъфет разкритикува „антикризисния“ данък на Обама
INSURANCE.BG




Финансистът смята, че подобен данък е опит да бъдат наказани банкерите, представяйки ги като главни виновници за кризата


Легендарният инвеститор Уорън Бъфет разкритикува предложението на американския президент Барак Обама да наложи с допълнителен данък и избирателно някои от водещите финансови компании в САЩ. По думите му „антикризисния“ налог е излишен, тъй като компании като Goldman Sachs Group Inc. и Wells Fargo & Co, вече върнаха на държавата кредитите,у които им бяха отпуснати в разгара на кризата, съобщи „Блумбърг“.
"Не виждам никакви причини те да плащат специалния данък.
Поддръжниците на този план просто искат да накажат хората, а аз не виждам смисъл от това", е заявил в интервю за телевизия „Блумбърг“.

Финансистът смята, че подобен данък е опит да бъдат наказани банкерите, представяйки ги като главни виновници за кризата. "Вижте щетите, които нанесоха ипотечните компании Fannie и Freddie, които бяха управлявани от Конгреса. 

Вероятно си струва да бъде въведен данък за конгресмените, тъй като допуснаха това да се случи с Freddie и Fannie?", е посочил Бъфет.
Президентът Обама обяви миналата седмица инициативата за въвеждане на данък върху 50-те водещи финансови компании в страната (35 американски и и 15 подразделения на чужди компании), с който да се покрие дупката в бюджета в размер на $117 млрд., образувана с финансирането на програмата в помощ на финансовия сектор (TARP).
Според замисъла на Белия дом налогът ще обхване компании, чиито активи надхвърлят $50 млрд.
В същото време многобройни хедж фондове, водещият застраховател American International Group, както и закъсалите ипотечни гиганти Fannie Mae и Freddie Mac, които заедно с водещите банки получиха огромна държавна помощ в разгара на кризата, ще бъдат освободени от плащането на данъка.
Така облагането на определена група финансови компании, а не сектора като цяло може да бъде изтълкувано от съда като нарушение на законодателството.

Според оценки на Morgan Stanley, най-големи суми ще трябва да заплатят Citigroup ($2,2 млрд..), J.P.Morgan Chase ($2,1 млрд.) и Bank of America Merrill Lynch ($2,1 млрд.). 

Да развъържат кесиите ще се наложи и на някои чуждестранни големи играчи, работещи в САЩ - Barclays ($560 млн.), Deutsche Bank ($551 млн.) и HSBC ($430 млн.
Целта на новия данък е да бъдат набрани до $90 млрд. в следващите 10 години.
Корейският гигант POSCO – с най-силна печалба от 6 тримесечия насам
14 януари, 2010 (27)


Южнокорейската POSCO, най-печелившата азиатска стоманодобивна компания обяви най-голямата си печалба за последните 6 тримесечия и съобщи, че ще купи дял в австралийска мина за желязна руда, заради завръщането на търсенето на световните пазари.

Печалбата на компанията скача със 77% до 1,28 трилиона вона (1,1 милиарда долара) за тримесечието, приключило на 31 декември, спрямо 721,4 милиарда вона преди година.

Пазарът на стомана ще отчете растеж от 9,2% през 2010 година заради възстановяването в световната икономика, прогнозираха от Световната асоциация по стоманата.

POSCO планира експанзия на стойност 30 милиарда долара в Азия, а днес съобщи, че може да придобие до 15% от мината Рой Хил в Австралия.


„Виждам дори по-силна печалба за POSCO през настоящата година, защото вярвам, че китайската икономика ще се справи по-добре от това, което мнозина очакват” – коментира Ченг Ин Уан, президент на KTB Asset Management в Сеул.

Акциите на стоманодобивната компания, дял в която има и Уорън Бъфет паднаха с 0,7% по време на днешната търговия.

Капиталовите разходи на компанията за 2010 година почти ще се удвоят до 9,3 трилиона вона. Компанията планира да увеличи производството на стомана с 16,6%, а предвижда и намаляване на разходите с 1,15 трилиона вона.
Акциите на POSCO скочиха заради желанието на Бъфет да увеличи дела си
20 януари, 2010 (34)

Акциите на южнокорейския стоманодобивен гигант POSCO затвориха снощи, по време на търговията в Ню Йорк с повишение от близо 5% след като от компанията съобщиха, че Уорън Бъфет иска да купи още акции от нея.

Berkshire Hathaway на Бъфет вече притежава 4,5% от POSCO.

Главният изпълнителен директор на корейската компания Джун-Янг Чун е имал среща с Бъфет в централата на Berkshire в Омаха, Небраска.


В съобщение, разпратено по мейла до медиите POSCO съобщават, че Бъфет е изявил желание по време на срещата да купи още акции и е изразил съжаление, че не го е направил миналата година, когато кризата доведе до срив в цената на акциите на корейската компания.

Цената им в края на 2009 година почти се утрои спрямо дъното от 47,09 долара.

Според агенция Блумбърг, ако Бъфет реши да продаде дела си в POSCO при сегашните пазарни цени той би реализирал чиста печалба от над 1,3 милиарда долара.

Бъфет: Няма да купувам още акции в POSCO
21 януари, 2010 (28)
Виж коментарите
Коментирай

Уорън Бъфет заяви, че неговата Berkshire Hathaway не планира покупката на нови акции от корейския стоманодобивен гигант POSCO, като по този начин сложи край на спекулациите, че ще увеличи 4,5-процентовия си дял в четвъртия по големина стоманодобивен концерн в света.

По-рано през седмицата от корейската компания съобщиха, че по време на визитата на изпълнителния директор Чун Джун-Янг в понеделник в Омаха, Небраска Бъфет е заявил, че иска да купи още акции на компанията, след като е пропуснал да се възползва от срива в цената им през 2009.

Акциите на компанията отбелязаха ръст след цитирането на въпросните коментари, но снощи Бъфет заяви, че пазарите са го разбрали грешно.

„Мисля, че трябва да поработя по корейския си още малко.

Казах, че харесвам компанията много и казах, че ми се ще да бях купил още, когато акцията падна миналата година…Чудесна компания е, но не планирам да купувам още акции”


Да припомним, че цената на акциите на POSCO в момента е близо тройно по-висока спрямо дъното, достигнато миналата година.

Все пак, според публикации в аналитичните издания Бъфет към момента е на „печалба на хартия” от 1,5 милиарда долара от инвестицията си.

сряда, 20 януари 2010 г.

A Millionaire

In 1962, Buffett became a millionaire, because of Buffett's partnerships, which in January 1962, had in excess of $7,178,500, of which over $1,025,000 belonged to Buffett.

Buffett merged all his partnerships into one partnership. 


Buffett discovered a textile manufacturing firm, Berkshire Hathaway and Buffett's partnerships began purchasing shares at $7.60 per share.

In 1965, when Buffett's partnerships paid $14.86 per share while the company had working capital (current assets minus current liabilities) of $19 per share. 


This did not include the value of fixed assets (factory and equipment).

Buffett took control of Berkshire Hathaway at the board meeting and named a new president, Ken Chace, to run the company. In 1966, Buffett closed the partnership to new money. 


In a second letter, Buffett announced his first investment in a private business — Hochschild, Kohn and Co, a privately owned Baltimore department store.

In 1967, Berkshire paid out its first and only dividend of 10 cents. 


In 1969, following his most successful year, Buffett liquidated the partnership and transferred their assets to his partners. Among the assets paid out were shares of Berkshire Hathaway.

In 1970, as chairman of Berkshire Hathaway, Buffett began writing his now-famous annual letters to shareholders.
Скоро всеки ще може да стане акционер в компанията на Бъфет
20.01.2010 14:48


Много скоро всеки ще може да стане акционер в инвестиционната компания Berkshire Hathaway, която се управлява от прочутия милиардер Уорън Бъфет. Цената на книжата на Berkshire Hathaway ще стане много по-достъпна за обикновените инвеститори заради планирания сплит на акциите, пише Fortune.

Berkshire Hathaway се търгува на Нюйоркската фондова борса, като компанията има два вида акции: клас А и клас Б. До края на вчерашната търговска сесия акциите клас А поскъпнаха с 2,6% до внушителните 100 030 долара, а цената на книжата клас Б се повиши също с 2,6% до 3 332 долара за акция.

Най-прочутият американски инвеститор, който е и един от най-богатите хора на планетата, ще проведе днес Общо събрание на акционерите в Berkshire, които трябва да одобрят предложения сплит от 50:1, който ще засегне само книжата от клас Б. Така цената им ще падне до около 66 долара за акция.

Този ход бе одобрен от Борда на директорите на Berkshire Hathaway в края на 2009 г. и се очаква да бъде приет единодушно и от нейните акционери. Така Berkshire ще може да привлече нови инвеститори, след като книжата й бяха трудно достъпни в продължение на много години заради високата си цена.

Конкретната причина за планирания сплит на акциите всъщност е покупката на железопътната компания Burlington Northern за 34 млрд. долара, която бе обявена през ноември 2009 г. Сделката предвижда част сумата да се изплати в брой, а другата част ще бъде под формата на акции на Berkshire.

Благодарение на сплита цената на акциите на Berkshire ще стане значително по-ниска. Така ще се улесни заплащането на тази част от обезщетението за акционерите на Burlington Northern, която е под формата на акции на Berkshire. Сделката се очаква да бъде финализира в началото на тази година.

През миналата година Бъфет нарече покупката на железопътната компания Burlington „ключов залог за икономическото бъдеще на Съединените щати“.

Днешното решение за сплит на акциите на инвестиционната компания ще бъде втората подобна промяна в структурата на акционерния капитал в 55-годишната история на Berkshire Hathaway. В момента цената на акциите клас Б, които се търгуват от 1996 г., е фиксирана на 1/30 от тази на акциите клас А.

След днешния вот съотношението ще се промени на 1/1 500. Търговията с акции на Berkshire от клас Б се активизира в края на 90-те години на 20 век, когато Уорън Бъфет започна да ги използва за различни придобивания. Среднодневният изтъргуван обем надминава 1 млн. акции всеки месец от 2006 г.

вторник, 19 януари 2010 г.

В същото време застрахователят Swiss Re отчете печалба през третото тримесечие, което надмина очакванията на анализатори, предаде Ройтерс.

Kомпанията заяви, че засега не възнамерява да връща огромния заем, който милиардерът Уорън Бъфет й отпусна в най-тежките месеци на кризата.


Нетната печалба на Swiss Re за третото тримесечие на 2009 г. достигна до 323 млн. долара (334 млн. франка).

Доброто й представяне се отдава на успешното преструктуриране на бизнеса.

Главният финансов директор на Swiss Re Джордж Куин заяви, че не се обмисля преждевременно връщане на 3-годишния заем, който включва купон от 12%.

Ранното му погасяване би било съпътствано със солидна наказателна такса.


Инвеститорите в момента си задават въпроса кога вторият по големина презстраховател в света ще се разплати с Бъфет.

Той инжектира 2.9 млрд. долара в Swiss Re в началото на годината, когато компанията отписа неликвидни активи за милиарди долари.

HOW TO THINK LIKE  BENJAMIN GRAHAM
AND INVEST LIKE
WARREN BUFFETT


  
  
 

Chapter 1. Mr. Market’s Bipolar Disorder 3
Swings, Bubbles, and Crashes / 5
Be an Anomaly / 11
Barrel of Monkeys? / 12

Chapter 2. Prozac Market 17
Obscurity / 17
Simplicity / 18
The Perfec tDream / 22
Tidying Up the Tale / 28

Chapter 3. Chaotic Market 33
New Wave / 33
Nex tWave / 36
Complexity / 46
Behavioral Finance / 47

Chapter 4. Amplified Volatility 51
Information Volatility / 51
Transaction Volatility / 59
Trader Volatility / 63
Prognosis / 66

Chapter 5. Take the Fifth 69
Who’s in Charge? / 70
Sticking to Your Kni ing / 71
Alchemy / 81
The Long Run / 86

v



SHOW ME THE MONEY 89

Chapter 6. Apple Trees and Experience 91
Fools and Wisdom / 91
Horse Sense / 100

Chapter 7. Your Circle of Competence 105
The Initial Circle / 106
The Nurtured Circle / 109
A Full Circle / 114
Decision Making / 116

Chapter 8. Recognizing Success 119
Business Fuel / 120
Managers under the Microscope / 124
Bang for the Buck / 128
The Full Tool Ches t/ 131

Chapter 9. You Make the Call 133
Assets / 134
Earnings / 138
Silver Bullets and the Margin of Safety / 142
Cash / 144
Marke tCircularity / 146

Chapter 10. Making (Up) Numbers 153
Perennials / 153
Satire / 157
Charades / 162
Coda / 167

PAR TIII:
IN MANAGERS WE TRUS T169

Chapter 11. Going Global 171
The Two-World Story / 172
Illusions of Duty / 176
One World to Come / 180


Contents vii

Chapter 12. Rules and Trust 193
The Family Manager / 193
Local Governance / 195
General Governance / 200
Your Voice a he Table / 202

Chapter 13. Directors at Work 205
Hail to the Chief / 206
Pay / 207
Deals / 212
Capital / 215
Checking Up / 217

Chapter 14. The Fireside CEO 221
Master Servants / 221
Action / 222
Lights / 230
Trus t/ 235

Conclusion: The V Culture 243
 


БЛАГОДАРНОСТИ той основните идеи в тази буу ktrace интелектуалната си линия до TBenjamin Греъм, когото никога не съм знаел, но трябва да от-kpost humously, и Уорън Бъфет, който имам голям късмет да се знаем и от чиито писания, разговори, разговори и съм Натрупаните знания и прозрение. Нито един от тези мъже, разбира се, е никаква отговорност за съдържанието тази книга и без съмнение ще Disa - Gree с някои от това, което казва, че той е написан като разказ тълкуването на принципите, които те развити, за които той се опитва да се верен. Г-н Бъфет заслужава си продължава благодарение на мен, позволяващи да се подготвя колекция от неговите писма до акционерите на Berkshire Хатауей, есетата на Уорън Бъфет: Уроци за Корпоративна Amer - Ика, както и за участие заедно с Berkshire заместник-председател Чарлз Munger в симпозиум организиран аз да го анализираме. Благодарности също така на читателите на тази колекция от прекрасни писания за BG - couraging ме да пиша в момента книга, особено смел колеж и преподаватели в бизнес училище, които използват техните роднини, че марихуана курсове и много хора, които ми кажете колко ценно е то. Други фенове на този буу kwho насърчава ме да пиша това са моите приятели в Morgan Stanley Dean Witter, водена от Дейвид Darst и Джон Шнайдер; Крис Дейвис и KimMarie Zamot на избраните съветници Дейвис; екипът на Едуард Г. Джоунс; и поддръжници, твърде много, за да спомена и на други фирми, които ценят бизнес анализ на начина на инвестиране. Чрез обучение и професионален навик съм корпоративен адвокат, и както моите ученици знаят, ефективност като корпоративен адвокат изисква мастеринг не само (или предимно) законодателство, но и бизнес, включително и фи - Nance, счетоводство и управление. За ръководството в тази философия, аз от kmy приятели и бивши колеги Cravath, Swaine & Мур, както и, че фирмата клиент. Не всички юридическите факултети, признават пресечната точка на правото и бизнеса. 

Моите колеги в Юридическия факултет Кардосо направи и подкрепа моите изследвания и писане в областта на финанси, счетоводство и управление, които изглеждат на другите крачка отвъд право като такова. Сред тези колеги, специални благодарности на Монро Цена за въвеждане на мен toWarren Бъфет чрез взаимно си приятел Боб Денъм. За отпускане на безвъзмездни средства ING ми отпуск да отделят време, за да WOR Врани тази книга, аз особено от kDean Пол Verkuil и Дийн Майкъл Херц. Моите лични и институционални способността на ръста на тези и други лица е значително подпомогнато от Самуил и Рони Хейман, и двете nonpracticing адвокати и поразително талантливи бизнесмени, по - vestors и филантропи. Те надарена щедро на Самуил и Рони Хейман Център за корпоративно управление на Кардосо, многообразна програма, която директно, която изследва този кръг от дисциплини в обучението, научните изследвания, както и преглед на политиката. Моите собствени учители също заслужават моята благодарност, особено Елиът Вайс, сега професор в Университета на Аризона колеж по право, който отдавна ми обърна внимание на Греъм и Бъфет и идеи акции, които щедро богатството си на знания. За мен, позволяващи използва в модифицирана форма някои материали от textboo KWE работи по заедно. Аз също от kProfessor Джефри Бауман на Джорджтаун Университет Закона център и Западна група, че книгата издател. Благодаря също така на Запад група за допускане на мен да се използва в модифицирана форма някои материали от друга textboo Ки пише въведението профил ING и финансите за адвокати, което не е само за адвокати. Много благодаря на целия екип на McGraw-Hill за тяхното Con - fidence, ентусиазъм, и насоки, особено Kelli Кристиансен, Джефри Krames и Скот Amerman. Повечето от всички, благодарение на жена ми, Joanna Кънингам, който болки - takingly редактира целия ръкопис с прецизност и грация и насърчава ме всяка стъпка от пътя.



ВЪВЕДЕНИЕ: Въпрос НА КУЛТУРАТА БЩ смисъл е сърцето на инвестирането и управлението на бизнеса. Но парадокса на здравия разум е, че тя е толкова uncom - пн Например, хората често се отнасят до stoc Кор пазарното ниво или като "надценени" или "подценено." Това е един празен израз. А делът на stoc Кор сборът от всички акции в havean пазарен индекс истинската стойност. Това е сумата на всички бъдещи парични потоци, в която акцията или индексът ще генерира в бъдеще, дисконтират до сегашната стойност. Оценявайки, че размерът на паричните потоци и за сегашния си aredifficult стойност. Но това определя стойност, и тя да е същата без оглед на това, което хората да се надяват и предполагам, че е. В резултат на надеждата и гадаете-понякога продукт за анализ, често не-е цената на акциите или нивото на пазара. Така, че е по-точно да се отнася за stoc Кор пазарен индекс като скъп или underpriced, отколкото като надценена или подценена. Прозрението, че цените варират различно от основополагащите ценности е здрав разум, но тя противопоставя преобладават смисъл. Тънка kabout на tickersymbol за народен Nasdaq 100: QQQ. За пускане на пазара гении на Националната асоциация на дилърите на ценни книжа може да сте избрали В три Дама, защото е студено и brandable писмо (тънка KQ-подсказки). При избора на буквите N, A, S, D, и Q, обаче, те се - lected една (три пъти), който стои за оферта и unwit - tingly отразяват котировки култура от този quintessentially Нова Икономиката индексът е създаден в средата на 1999. Цитати на цените команда постоянно внимание в луд, МО - Ърн пазар, където купувачи и продавачи на запасите никаква представа на фирми зад хартия те суап но точно това, което е цената. Цитат мания търговия анализ за отношението, съзнанието за късоглед инерция, разузнавателни сведения за инстинкт. Котировки са банален диета на деня търговец, изграждане на казино култура, където бързината на действия, захранвани от ирационални импулси измества качество и количество XII Въведение: В културата на мисълта. QQQ е способен символ за най-летливи индекс stoc kmarket история. В културата Q, здравият разум е често срещана глупост, пускането цена на пиедестал и всичко, но игнорира бизнес стойност. Търговецът Q цена, като вижда всичко. Умният инвеститор знае каква стойност. Тя се фокусира върху стойността на първо място, а след това сравнява стойността на цена, за да видите Ако инвестиционен притежава обещание за добра възвръщаемост. Този вид на фокус изисква инвеститорът да работи като бизнес анализатор, не като пазарен анализатор или ценни книжа, анализатор и със сигурност не като Q търговеца. Това буу kdevelops един начин на мислене за бизнес анализ като антидот на културата Q. Той обсъжда инструментите на stoc kpicking и Акценти критични области на мислене за пазари и цени, и бизнеса и мениджъри. Тя изгражда latticewor KOF здравия разум да запълни по-голямата стойност в нищожен днешните пазари. В буу kfirst ви показва защо е грешка да се работи като анализатор на пазара или на тоалетната Кой пазара, за да разкрие стойност, когато всички itcan направите, е да разкрие цени. След това тя представя инструменти за тънка kabout производителност и стойност, но също така предупреждава за това как финансовата информация може да бъде нарушена по начини, които могат да ви подведе. Следователно, той твърди, че основен елемент на интелигентни инвестиции е Com - monsense способност за оценка на надеждността на корпоративните manag - ERS, главно на главния изпълнителен директор и съвет на директорите. Подходът бизнес анализ, които да инвестират разбива много митове на инвестиционни ерудиция преобладават в културата Q макар и не единствено за то в цялата история. Така например, той отхвърля разлика проникващ, тъй като е погрешно между ръста инвестиране и стойността инвестиции (или между ръста запаси и стойността на акции). Разбира се, някои Com - фирми проявяват повече обещание растеж на доходите в сравнение с други, но всички темпове на растеж са компонент на стойност, така че това разграничение, Crys - talized в началото на 1970 г. и все по-голям записа след това, не е от аналитична стойност. От друга страна, подходът бизнес анализ подчертава ключов разграничение между инвестиции, от една страна и спекулации или хазарт, от друга. Всички инвестиции включва RIS канд в този смисъл има спекулативен елемент във всяка от него. Интелигентна инвестиции, обаче, призовава за разумно определима оценка и сравнение на цените. Водещи примери да спекулира и хазарта включват хора, купуващи дялове в акции на компании или интернет стартиращи фирми знаят малко или нищо и за закупуване на акциите във всеки бизнес, без първо четене своя годишен доклад, или знаейки какво да тоалетната КФОР в него. За всеки хазарт история на успеха ви чувам за, има десетки неуспехи не. Тъй като The Wall Street Journal наскоро quipped, не брат на практика е някога е известно да разкрие колко пари той губи в stoc пазар. Акцентът върху бизнес анализ, за разлика от анализа на пазара е подсилен от въображаеми г-н пазар, създаден от двадесетия Най-ловки век мислител инвестиции и бизнес училище учител Бенджамин Греъм. Цена и стойност се различават в капиталовия пазар търговия, тъй като пазарът е най-добре характеризира като мания на депресия, най-вече било прекалено еуфорично или твърде мрачен. Това е в противоречие с популярен, но погрешно убеждение, че пазарите са ефективни и следователно точно цената на ценни книжа. След като сте като бизнес анализатор знае как да се търси, следващият въпрос е къде да търсите. Водеща идея е кръга на компетентността си, създаден от най-успешните инвеститори на двадесети век и предпри - ност педагог, Уорън Бъфет. Тя се определя от способността ви да махнете derstand на компанията продукти и оперативни контекст. Кръгове от компетентност, са толкова различни, колкото инвеститори, които трябва да ги дефинира. Всички инвеститорите трябва да грайфер с предизвикателството за използване на текущи и минали информация да се прецени бъдещите резултати на бизнеса. За повечето хора, тя е по-лесно да направите това с фирмите, които са е около дълго време, е чрез множество бизнес циклите, и изправени пред икономическа рецесия. В рамките на тази група от бизнеса са много чиито дълги Trac krecords оправдае се нарича класика-добре утвърдени фирми с мощни глобални продукти и пазарни PO - sitions като Procter & Gamble, GE, "Кока-Кола, и" Дисни ".

Някои от те ще издържат като stalwarts, докато други ще бъдат бити надолу (като GE е да Уестингхаус или като Wal-Mart е да Сиърс Roebuck). В способност да се каже коя е кой ще варира между хора с различни способности, в оценката на тези фирми, за различни набори от умения са необходими, за да разберат тези различни видове бизнес. Така също ще способности се различават по отношение на оценката на бъдещето на - фонд за изпълнение на новите компании, които са били по-малко чрез Varia - тия в своите оперативни климата. Това са "реколта бизнес" -- тези, които са били наоколо за известно време, но които работят в по-новите и по-динамични отрасли, които се развиват с бързи темпове дружества като Cisco, Intel, или "Майкрософт", например. Те са по-малко от Trac запис, и може да бъде по-трудно за много хора да разберат. Но някои XIV Въведение: В културата хората ще имат възможност да ги разбирам много добре и да се в състояние да вземат информирани решения за бъдещите им перспективи. Както и при класиците, реколта някои компании ще се окаже воини и други wimps. Например, да вземе персоналния компютър бизнес. От 1990 г. до 1999 г., някогашен стартиране Dell построили силно печеливши директно продажбите компютър бизнес, отглеждане на продажбите си и д - си на удивително ставки, с Compaq следните почтено, Тенди Ябълка и изостава, и изобилие от зашеметяващи wimps страдание ерозия по време на периода, включително AST, Digital, Atari, Tulip, Commodore, и Kaypro .* Трета група от дружества, са "новобранци" чисто нови дружества, може би в чисто нови индустрии, чието целия контекст на практика не Trac krecord. Те са границата на бизнеса, като стомана в своя ден, в техните автомобили, пластмаса и малко по-късно и в Интернет на началото на двадесет и първи век. Отделно от първия Movers в такива групи-казват, Yahoo! и America Online (AOL) сред 1990-те години Интернет компаниите-те почти няма икономическа история на SPEA KOF. Дори и така, ще има инвеститори, които имат до момента инструменти за ден да направи оценка на интелигентни, където новобранци ще бъде в бъдеще. При чифтосване с AOL през 2000 г., висши мениджъри на време - Уорнър, изразени точно такова доверие в способността им да го направят. Дали тяхната преценка ще бъдат оправдани остава да се види. Но със сигурност, въпреки че някои от тези фирми ще се окаже лети - по-нощи, други са истински "нагоре-посетител, който ще продължи до на звания от реколта воини, за да як класика. В крайна сметка, всеки Com - фирмата започна като новобранец. В главната особеност на кръга на компетентност, а след това, е, че той трябва да бъдат съобразени с индивидуалните. Той не е такъв, че интелигентните инвеститорите се избегне предприятията, които са трудно да се разбере, нито е обект на бързи промени. Напротив, тези инвеститори, оборудвани с способност и сила на духа да се разбере какво е трудно за другите да по - стоя и да се прецени по-добре от другите как бизнес и индустрия се развиват реши да има предимство. Но остава важен за всеки инвеститор да дойде да се пребори с това, което е и какво не е в рамките на кръга на компетентността му да направят информиран съдебни решения, че в telligent инвестирането изисква. * Кара Scannell, Анатомия на Bull Run: "новата икономика" на складовите срок за Разходи: Blast от миналото-А кът Ло вчерашния Техническа Инвестиции-A Few процъфтяват, Други Просто оцелеят, някои провали, The Wall Street Journal, 18 януари, 2000. Въведение: В култура XV Следващото проучване е какво да тоалетната КФОР, в кръга си от Com - petence. Основният въпрос е за сигурност, с които можете да оценка на дългосрочните икономически характеристики на бизнес. Един по-голяма степен на увереност може да се наложи за новобранци, по-малко за реколта компании, и най-малко за класика, но във всички случаи, оценка на в дългосрочен план характеристики на бизнес резултатите е от решаващо значение. Получаването на необходимата степен на доверие в оценката води само няколко количествени проучвания. Вие ще видите във втората част на буу kthat финансови отчети трябва да ви позволи да отговори на три въпроси за бизнес: • Как вероятно е бизнес ще бъде в състояние да изплаща дълговете си, тъй като те се дължи? • Как работи добре, е управление на бизнеса? • Какво е то си струва? Тези въпроси могат да се измери с достатъчна степен на Кон - fidence с основен запознатостта с ключови бизнес съотношения, свързани с оборотен капитал и дълг, управление на инвентара и други краткосрочни план активите, възвръщаемост на собствения капитал, както и бъдещи печалби outloo КФОР. Така, както всеки инвеститор кръга на компетентност ще се променят, така също ще оценката на тези финансови характеристики. В крайна сметка, стойност на една фирма е сегашната стойност на всички пари той ще генерира за своите собственици през бъдеще време. Защото никой не може да знае бъдещето с увереност, идва с този номер се изисква правото, на средства и добра преценка. Оборудван с тези средства и труд в своя кръг от компетентност, можете да определите колко и какви EVI - симост е необходимо да се чувстваш удобно с оценка оценка. Още няма едно надеждно средство да определят стойността на бизнес, толкова интелигентни инвеститори трябва да спазват Бенджамин Греъм и Уорън Кардинал Бъфет върховенството на разумно инвестиране: Първи марж на безопасност между цената, която плащате и ти стойност се плаща за. В осъществяването на всички тези разследвания, съобщава цифри трябва да бъдат лекувани със здравословен скептицизъм. Счетоводство конвенции и присъдите на - менти могат да нарушат реалност бизнес. За пример, оборотен капитал смокинов Ures в процеса може да бъде нарушено от счетоводните правила, свързани с инвентаризацията и събиране на вземанията. Някои от дълготрайните материални активи, които са остаряла или не - конкурентни могат да имат действително начин скрап стойност по-малко от ре - пренесли фигура. XVI Въведение: В културата От друга страна, някои активи могат да бъдат занижени въз основа на баланс лист (като резерви на дружеството природен газ, както и земя стойности). Off-пасиви на баланса, свързани с околната среда проб - lems, след пенсионирането ползи за здравето на работниците и служителите, и stoc Kop - тия за мениджъри също трябва да бъдат включени като промените докладвани цифри. Не е необходимо да знае всеки детайл, но работна разбиране е необходимо и може да се развива с малко количество усилия, като част на ум бизнес анализ настроени. Вързан с въпроса за сигурност при оценката на дългосрочните характеристиките на даден бизнес е на сигурност, с която можете да разчитате при управление на канал награди на акционерите. Той остава вярно, че апетитни икономика е най-важната променлива при оценяване на всеки бизнес, за инвестиции. Лош икономика може да рядко, ако изобщо се лекува, дори и от изключителни управление, и по - ferior управление може да навреди на един добър бизнес (въпреки че е по-трудно за лошо управление, за да попречи на неизпълнени бизнес). Това управление реалността заедно с неадекватността на мар - kets и потенциалната ненадеждност на числа изисква една инвеститор също ценят качествените измерения на бизнес-анален ysis. Най-важните от тях са тези качества, които показват, че дадена компания е собственик ориентация. Холдинг собственик ориентация не се изисква от корпоративни човека AGERS като въпрос на закона, или дори от практиката или обичай. Също така няма такива собственик ориентация да бъде постигнато само чрез организиране на корпоративни правилата по определен начин, като с голям брой извън ди - ректори, или разделяне на функциите на изпълнителен директор и председател на на борда. Съответно, фокусът върху мениджърите е акцент върху доверие достойнство. Оценка на надеждността на корпоративните мениджъри е много подобен оценка на надеждността на бъдещите син-в закона. Това е мат - трето от здравия разум-пак, рядко, но придобие и нагласа. В контекста на корпоративните мениджъри, източници на вникване в управленски надеждност включва търговските регистри и качествата на комуни - ставят на акционерите на писмо-изпълнителен директор в частност. Примери на това изкуство омахвам книга, последната глава дава сметка за буквите на kWelch Jac (GE), Майк Айснър (Disney), и края на Роберто Гоизуета (Кока-Кола). В Фол kwisdom на "отглеждането на вашия PS И Дама" не се отнася до цени и цитати, но на здравия разум. В инвестиране, това означава, овладее основите на финанси, счетоводство и управление, за да видите на следните обстоятелства: Въведение: В културата XVII • Ефективното история пазар е най-много четири пети вярно и инвеститори могат да се възползват от останалата една пета • традиционните методи на финансов анализ на инвеститора остават най-добрите приятели, но, че приходите от управление и manipula-счетоводни TION може да си най-големите врагове • Интелигентни инвеститори обръщат специално внимание на ръководителите, които са и дали те са верни Отглеждането на тези PS И Дама не изисква огромни количества на работа, въпреки че не изисква големи дози на здрав разум като ваксинация срещу треска Q. Антидот Това ще ви отведе до златните порти на по-безопасни и по-проспериращите култура V света. В ненадминат учител на V култура, Бен Греъм, беше също така успешно практикуващ лекар. Уорън Бъфет, за съвършенство на студенти и лекари, също е учител. Всички добри студенти да уроците на учителите си и се разшири обхвата им приложение. Бъфет не е изключение, нито са много други Греъм учениците, които приемат основните поуки и да ги разшири в разнообразие на успешни начини. † Но разликите са по-фините да кажа най-малко. Бъфет поддържа - Греъм нарушават основните идеи, които призовават за бизнес анализ ум - в стаята, вниманието към различията между цена и стойност, и по - sisting на марж на безопасност, когато прави инвестиция. Само малки разлики в прилагането излезе, включително и доста много се ограничават до следното: Бъфет места, малко по-голямо значение за ролята на мениджърите в инвестиции, е по-малко задължен да се пазариш покупките на Греъм предпочитан тип, е малко по-малко ангажирани с диверсификация на stoc kinvestment, и плаща повече внимание на по - материални ценности актив, отколкото Греъм. Но тези различия не са само засенчена от това, което е често срещано, те също са отражение на по-широк обединяващ принцип: значението на независими решения в по - придобиване. Други ученици Греъм избират различни начини за прилагане на Основните идеи някои разнообразяване неимоверно, други концентриране неимоверно, а някои разплащателни далеч повече или по-малко внимание на ООН derlying естеството на бизнеса. С дързост и голямо смирение, това буу koffers сметка на идеи на Греъм и разширяване Бъфет и прилагането на ония, които отразяват пример и традиция. Това е † Уорън Бъфет, за Superinvestors на Греъм и Doddsville, Хермес (Колумб - BIA Business School), есен 1984. XVIII Въведение: В културата една разширена и разширен разказ, свързани конкретно с Con - временно инвестиране среда, която очевидно не може Греъм вече адрес и Бъфет, че може да направи само в относително струк - tured framewor KOF годишен писма акционер. По всяко време, умът бизнес анализ зададени е заложена в цена-разграничение стойност и марж на безопасност-принцип, дълбоко Moorings на културата V, на деканите на които винаги ще бъдат Греъм и Бъфет, въпреки че аз съм щастлив да бъда на факултета. П А Р I T A Tale НА ДВЕ ПАЗАРИ Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc Щракнете тук за Условия за ползване С ч T R A P E 1 MR. Пазар Биполярно разстройство той пациента показва класически маниакална депресия или биполярно disor - Tder-съчетаване на епизоди на еуфория с раздразнение. Той продължава да диви sprees разходи за месеци наред, като се използват парите, които не трябва да купуват неща, той не се нуждае. В периоди той е стабилна приказлив и пълен с идеи, но само в разсеян, zigzaggy начини. Той може да ви очарова в закупуване на Бруклинския мост. После, внезапно и бързо, той смени настроения, които попадат в един месец през целия период на KDE-Dar pression, често е предизвикано от най-малките неприятности, като например малки Лошата новина и скромно разочароващи резултати. Експертите отбелязват, че състоянието може да се наследяват, причинени от вродена химия, засягащи настроение, апетит, и възприемането на болка, която от своя страна може да доведе до драматични печалби тегло, последван от рязко загуби тегло. Има предпазни мрежи да падне BAC Врани, като подкрепа от правителството и одобрени от правителството лечение, като стабилизатори на настроението. Но пациентът живее в отрицание и може да стане ядосани и подозрителни, понякога не приема на лекарството и предварително cipitating по-интензивно се пристъпи на възходи и падения. Пациентът съм описва, разбира се, е stoc kmarket. Него смеси епизоди на ирационален страх с епизоди на ирационални алчност. Него се издига с масивна инфузии на средства-често привлечени-после пада след оттеглянето на тези средства. Той отскача около като цирк клоун на Pogo Stick, тъкане диви разкази за несметно богатство да се направи без усилие. След това pouts, plummets и коригира, често за новини , че тази или, че дружеството не успя да отговори само чрез печалба оценки пари за акция. Ясно мислители за пазарно поведение правилно смятат, че това състояние е нелечимо, като на пазара са склонни към мазнини печалби Фол - lowed от мазнини без загуби връзката с бизнеса или икономическата реалност. Въпреки това, правителството двигатели, като по ценни книжа и Размяна на Комисията и частни такива като Ню kStoc Yor 3 Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc Щракнете тук за Условия за ползване 4 Приказка за двата пазара Размяна наблюдава крайности, за налагане на "прекъсвачи", че затвори пазара на определени при това заплашва да се промъкне в пристъп на де - pression (разпродаване) или повишаване на изискванията за маржин сметки, особено тези на ден търговците. И все пак не се лекува в очите. Г-н пазар, от гледна точка Бен Греъм, отрича своята мания depression.1 Той прави това в многобройни проучвания франко ишлеме как "рационално" е. Това го прави в безброй разговори и публикации, отнасящи се до неговата "ефективност." Reams на "бета книги" са съставена в убеждението, че си gyrations лесно и точно да отразява точно измерими запаси RIS kthat поза за инвеститорите. Анотация съвети за диверсификация на портфейлите се продава като единственият начин да се сведе до минимум рационално RIS kthat този ефикасна система за manageably подаръци. Отричане предотвратява лечение. Обърнете Бен Греъм г-н Пазар диагностична стъпка по-дълбоко. Мали cious микроорганизми наречен Rickettsia (на името на д-р Хауърд T. Рикетс, 1871-1910) предизвика болести като тиф. От Gree дума за "ступор" означаваше състояние на безчувственост и психическо Con - синтез, тиф се характеризира с пристъпи на депресия и делириум. Тя се предава от Bloodsucking наречен паразити кърлежи. Тези ал - обекти предават подобна болест, наречена Ку-треска. За да се избегне Ку-треска, тези потопила в цъкане, заразено с гори предварително беля си. Шапки, ръкавици, с дълги ръкави, и панталони са рокля код. Ако ухапан, разумно обитателите горски премахване на паразита с пинцети, измийте захапка, и се прилагат триене алкохол, лед, и calamine лосион. Те да оцелеят и да се насладите на гората. Глупаците в цъкане настройка горски отида роди, оставяйки кожата си изложени и най-смело, главите им. След като намерите кърлеж, страх дискове да ирационални действия, като например изгарянето на тик-kinstead на tweez ING го. Царе и царици на fooldom след това предприятие радостно на техните горски експедиция, лекомислено не знае, че те са заразени с Ку-треска-до депресия и делириум, определени инча В stoc kmarket гора, кърлежи на ценови оферти инфектират неподготвен глупаци по същия начин и с подобни резултати. Търговец манията се разпространява с котировките на треската Q епидемия, добавяйки газ за огъня на маниакална депресия г-н пазар. Когато се осмелява да навлезе в stoc kmarket, защитава само себе си като бихте когато туризъм в гората въоръжени за борба с блага смучене паразит на кърлежи по свинете Q цена. Бен Греъм и Уорън Бъфет предписват същия курс за справяне с г-н пазар. Те посъветва, че точно, защото не е глупаво да се признават неговите симптоми или диагностициране на болестта си, тя е също толкова глупаво да се играе в тях или бивши Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 5 представляват себе си на зараза. Вместо това, използвайте г-н пазар за вашата реклама - Vantage. Нито г-н Греъм пазар, нито тази метафора предполага по свинете Q нищо за психологията на участниците на пазара. Рационално ко - PLE действат самостоятелно може да доведе до ирационални резултати на пазара. Много инвеститори просто отстъпват на експерти или мнозинство становище. Следващ стадото може да изглежда разумно и интелигентно, докато stampedes директно от скалите. Люлки, мехурчета, и трясък Цена кърлежи карам дивата природа колебания, че язвите съвременни stoc пазари. Импулс търговци и сектор ротатори са жертви, така и предаватели на свинете Q. Заболяването достига епидемични размери когато тълпата следва "незаличимо посочена тенденция" в сар - castic думите на Фред Schwed от класическите му WOR Къде са Клиентите яхти? , отнасящи се до илюзията, че моделите предсказуемо persist.2 Средна stoc kprices суинг с 50% всяка година, а извършените бизнес стойност е далеч по-стабилна. Сподели оборотът е огромен. В броя на акциите, търгувани в сравнение с всички дялове за неизпълнени шип от 42% до 78% на Нова kStoc kExchange Yor между 1982 г. и 1999 г. и от 88% до 221% на Nasdaq в периода между 1990 1999,3 и цените на определени запаси нараснат драстично и да падне яростно в рамките на дни и седмици без никакви LIN Кой основните Вал бизнес УЕП. Спекулациите Rages, както и скоростта на цената на отклонение е MUL - tiplied драстично в сравнение с предходните десетилетия. Пазарната волатилност се е увеличил приблизително пропорционално на драматичното нарастване на по - формиране-реални и въображаеми-така че е лесно достъпна. Махни - Ting в преди изгрев и преди падането се превърна в ден търговеца мантра, която разкрива не само присъствието на г-н Пазар но съществуването му coconspirators с хиляди. Влакче в увеселителен парк вози в stoc klevels са били известни на цялата историята на организирани борси пазара, но те вози прекалено КМА - JOR индекси нагоре или надолу заедно. Съвсем различен е пътека пламна в края на 1990-те и началото на 2000 г. като средно Дау Джоунс на водещи индустриални фирми отиде един начин и Nasdaq AV - erage на по-технологична насоченост или по-млади компании отиде един - друг.


6 Приказка за двата пазара Пенлива новата икономика поклонник оферта за създаване на нови акции и технологии складове на диви височини в сравнение с техните жалки или отрицателни печелят - сгради, докато избягвам на натъпкан със старите икономика, която продължава да генерира стабилен увеличава приходите. Новият виене на свят утихна, и Dow нарасна, докато Nasdaq смъкна. Но тогава една ре - предмет, а други намаляват. Хаос е само описание за това диви света. Всеки, който иска да божествен някои дълбоко логика в тези флип-flopping модели, обаче, може да спре гледам на 14 април 2000 г., когато индекси падна заедно, Dow с 6%, а Nasdaq с 10%. Тогава и двамата борби на следващия ден за търгуване, с Дау катерене BAC knearly 3%, а Nasdaq се движат BAC kup 6,6% (и деня след това изпитват на помпи от близо 2% и над 7%, съответно - относително). Не дълбока логика обяснява тези swoons или това ценообразуване различия и всичко, което наистина може да сключва е, че г-н пазар е като си (ООН) обичайните себе си. Разпределяне тъй като тези данни са твърде помисли, че в първото тримесечие на 2000 г., Nasdaq, претърпени четири откаже от 10% или все повече и след това във всеки случай борби. През април 2000 г. говорим, че е ре - опънат два скока, които са му най-големият в историята и три капки , които са били най-големите си в историята. В края на 1990-те и началото на 2000 г., Dow бюстове са еднакво често срещано, както и други капки за повече от 3% шоу (виж Таблица 1-1). Индексът Dow бюстове на август 1998 г. са особено мощни: Те унищожена всички печалби на Дау са направени през тази година. Така беше през март 2000 година бюст: Това определя Dow BAC Кой където тя е била за една година по-рано. Ако предпочитате да се съсредоточи върху еуфория г-н пазара, да вземе залпове Таблица 1-1. Dow Busts Точка Процент Дата Затвори Промяна на климата 27-ми октомври 1997 7,161.15 554,26 7,18 4-ти август 1998 година 8,487.31 299,43 3,41 27-ми август 1998 8,165.99 357,36 4,19 31ви август 1998 година 7,539.07 512,61 6,37 4-ти януари 2000 год. 10,997.93 359,58 3,17 7-ми март 2000 9,796.03 374,47 3,68 Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 7 Таблица 1-2. Dow залпове Точка Процент Дата Затвори Промяна на климата 2-ри септември 1997 година 7,879.78 257,36 3,38 28-ми октомври 1997 година 7,498.32 337,17 4,71 1-ви септември 1998 7,827.43 288,36 3,82 8-ми септември, 1998 8,020.78 380,53 4,98 23-ти Септември 1998 8,154.41 257,21 3,26 15-ти Октомври, 1998 8,299.36 330,58 4,15 15-ти март 2000 10,131.41 320,17 3,26 16-ти март 2000 година 10,630.60 499,19 4,93 в Dow над 3%, което става в края на 1990-те и началото на 2000 (виж Таблица 1-2). Отделно от големината, помисли за близостта на тези Дау бюстове и разрушава. В диаграми показват две гръб-към-BAC kreversals: The 27-ми октомври 1997, бюст на 7,18% бе последвано на следващия ден от 4,71% се пукна и 31ви август 1998 година, бюст на 6,37% бе последвано на следващия ден от 3,82% се пръсне. Трите бюстове на август 1998 г. са незабавно последван от три залпове от септември 1998 г., много по начина, по който бюст на 7-ми март 2000 година, беше последвана от залпове на 15 март и 16 от тази година. Трудно е да се смята, че тези последователни залпове и бюстове са въз основа на промените в основните права на разследвания на информация тори са рационално и ефективно действаща от. Отвъд бюстове и залпове на Dow и на Nasdaq в края на 1990-те и началото на 2000 г., припомни един от най-драматичните един епи - sodes на присъствието на г-н пазар на Уолстрийт: от 1987 г. катастрофата. В Dow изпарили от 22,6% за един ден и почти 33% в течение на един месец. От 1987 г. катастрофата не е ограничено до 30 обикновени акции на Dow, но е по целия свят. The New Yor kStoc Борса, Лондон Stoc kExchange и Токио Stoc Размяна всички разбил. Ако stoc kmarket цени наистина слушали все по-популярни ефективно пазар теория (EMT) и точно да отразява информация за бизнес ценности, някои важни промени в тялото на наличната инфор - информация ще се изисква да доказва, че катастрофата. Много хора се опитаха да Обясни като рационален отговор на редица промени и в около средата на октомври 1987 г., включително следните: 8 Приказка за двата пазара • На 4 септември 1987 г., Федералният резерв повиши раз - брой курс. • На 13 октомври 1987 г., Къща начини и средства комитет гласували да одобрят законодателството на данък общ доход, че ще забрани интерес удръжки върху дълга, използвани за финансиране на бизнес придобивания. • На 18 октомври, 1987, съкровищни секретар Джеймс Бейкър едно публично - nounced намерение за намаляване на стойността на долара. • Пазарните цени вече са били високи от исторически standards.4 Някои експерти приписва катастрофата от 1987 г. на различни институционални фактори, включително и програма за търговия и застрахователния портфейл, които са били в стаята да продаде големи парчета на портфейлите на големите инвеститори, тъй като цените повалям. Когато паднаха цените, тези продажби програма ги избутал определени дори по-трудно. Други експерти посочиха деривативни ценни книжа, често екзотични инструменти, чиято стойност се променя с промените в стойността на показатели, като например лихви и валутни курсове. Тези производни обикновено са предназначени за намаляване на колебанията в RIS канд такива пейка марка, въпреки че ако лошо проектирани да обостри волатилност stoc kmarket ценообразуване. Но като се има предвид международния характер на катастрофата и неговата дълбочина, Едва ли някой приема тези обяснения. Повечето хора също се договарят че е невъзможно да се обясни рационално радикални промени в цените които са се случили в други случаи, независимо дали 1929 катастрофата, от 1989 г. почивка, или общо 1990-те и 2000 волатилност. Пазар просто безумие не може да се обясни използването EMT, но е продукт на комплекс от сили в допълнение към реални промени в информацията за основните - умствени ценности бизнес. Пазар frenzies като те не са изолирани и със сигурност не уникални епизоди във финансовата история. Напротив, bub-пазар Bles ситуации, в които цените са далеч по-високи от стойностите се случи твърде често. Имаше една технология stoc kbubble от 1959 г. до 1961 г.; балон в така наречените "Nifty Петдесет запаси" в края на 1960 и началото на 1970; хазартна stoc kbubble през 1978 г.; балон на петрола и енергийни запаси в края на 1970; дом балон пазаруване през 1986 г. и 1987 г.; и биотехнологии балона в началото на 1990 (с resur - gence в началото на 2000 г.), и всички те приличат на Интернет или дот-ком балона от края на 1990-те и началото на 2000. Пазарната капитализация (цена пъти неизплатените акции) от Интернет сектор е около 1 трилион в началото на 2000 г., с продажбите на $ 30 млрд. загуби от $ 3 billion.5 През 1999 г. резултатите от първоначалното Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 9 публично предлагане (IPO на) на интернет запаси бяха започнати много в същия отрасъл, където ще бъде невъзможно да има повече от една шепа печеливши компании. Сделки включен, за изпита - PLE, 17 на здравеопазването свързани компании, седем бизнес-към-бизнес електронна търговия дружества, шест музикални компании разпределение, пет ем - ployee работодатели, и три туристически агенции. Тя започва да звучи като на "дванадесет дни на Коледа". Шофиране това финансиране е очарованието на технологично иноваци - иновационна, обаянието, които характеризират една предишна мехурчета пазар добре. 1960 балона технология произтичат от нововъведения, като например цветен телевизор и търговската авиация струя. Той зареди едно IPO бум в областта на електрониката и други фирми, чиито имена завърши с "Трон" или "onics" не, че за разлика от 1999 на дот-ком boom.6 поглъщания отчете ръст в двата периода, подхранван от високите цени stoc построени много kthat корпоративни империи. Всички TAL kwas на новата история-противодействие на ERA - нарича "нова парадигма" през 1960 и "новата икономика" в края на 1990-те и началото на 2000. Но тъй като Уорън Бъфет кавички Хърб Стайн като казва: "Ако нещо не може да продължава вечно, то ще приключи." 7 Балон в Интернет не може да свърши също така внезапно, както 1960 елек - tronics е балон. Тя може вместо това да следват пътя на stoc kmarket балон в Япония през 1980 г., която приключи през постепенно и общо ерозия на stoc kprices в EI Ni средно през десетилетието от 1990-те. Едно нещо, което двата периода са по-общ и един от най-забележителните общи характеристики на спекулативни мехури GEN - erally-е появата на "нови" начини за защита на високи цени. В Япония 1980 горивото е stoc kprices основава не на печелят - сгради или в брой, които могат да бъдат генерирани от бизнеса, но за извършените стойността на активите, собственост на фирми, които сами са били нараства до стратосферата, в резултат на агресивна спекулация недвижими имоти. Ние скоро ще видите, че същото алхимия язви началото на двадесет и първи век Съединените членки. Тези примери просто проявява в stoc kmarkets САЩ на емо - tional дискове, присъщи на човека участие на пазара, личи още като цяло не само от 1980-те японски опит, но с класически епизоди на биполярно разстройство, като Холандски мания луковица на лале на 1630s и британската South Sea жизнерадост точно преди 1720. Във всеки от тези случаи-както в повечето други-първоначалната причина да купя може да е било добро. Редки луковици лалета в Холандия са били ценен поради новостта на това цвете в Холандия, той се превърна в състояние символ. Акциите на South Sea Company Великобритания бяха ценни, когато тя започнала да упражнява своите кралски предоставяне на монопол търговията с Испания. 10 Приказка за двата пазара Но вълнението на "Първи в" по тези сделки излезе от контрол, все повече и повече пари бяха разпределени за фючърсни договори на лале луковици и акции на South Sea Company, и повече пари Това е довело там, че колкото повече пари сякаш следват-до музиката спря и паника в стаята инча В Холандия, имам толкова висока цена спекулантите, че не могат да си позволят да плащат за крушки са купи правата за. Във Великобритания, компанията просто не генерира големите печалби от търговията испански всеки имаше очевидно са бивши pecting. EMT Ако е вярно, САЩ stoc kmarkets ще бъде уникален сред всички пазари през човешката история и в целия Con - Помислете за това globe.8 временен избор от съчиненията на пазар наблюдател Жозеф дьо ла Вега от края 1600s за Амстердам stoc kexchanges му ден, в стила на един език, в Chee kdialogue между търговец и инвеститор: За партньори: Тези хора на фондовата борса са доста глупаво, пълен с по - стабилност, лудост, гордост и безумие. Те ще се продава без да знаят мотив, те ще купуват без да причина. Инвеститор: "Те са много умни в изобретяването на причините за нарастване на цена на акциите на случаи, когато е налице спад тенденция, или за спад в средата на бум. Това е пар - ticularly струва отбелязвайки, че в този ад има хазарт са два класа на спекулантите. В първа класа се състои от на бикове. Втората фракция се състои от мечките. В бикове са като на жираф, който е страх от нищо. Те обичам всичко, те хвалят всичко, те преувеличават всичко. Те не са впечатлени от пожар или нарушен от провал. Мечките, напротив, са напълно управляван от страх, безпокойство и нервност. Зайците се - идват слонове, свади в механа станат бунтове, слаб сенките изглеждат като тях признаци на хаос. Падането на цените не трябва да има граница, и там са също unlim - ограничените възможности за възход. Поради прекомерно високи стойности не трябва аларма you.9 Ви звучи познато? Защо, освен от надменността и chutzpah, трябва да Ние вярваме, че САЩ stoc kmarkets са толкова специално в историята на свят? Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 11 СЕ аномалия EMT също не може да обясни много други неща за това как пазарните цени работят с изключение на люлки, мехурчета и катастрофи. Множество доказателства опровергават EMT включва извънредни броя на необяснима пазар явления, като например следните:

• Ефектът януари (цените са склонни да се покачва през януари). • The Insider ефект (цена на фондова's тенденция да се увеличава след вътрешни раз - близо до покупки на ценни книжа и борси и Комисията да е след вътрешна продажбите са разкрити). • Ефектът стойност линия (запаси оценени високо от стойностите Line In - одежда изследването са склонни да надмине пазара в условията на цените). • Аналитикът ефект (акции на дружества, последвано от по-малко анализатори са склонни да станат pricier в сравнение с тези, последвано от по-ана - lysts). • Месец ефект (stoc kprices са склонни да се покачва в края и на началото на месеца). • Уикендът ефект (stoc kprices са склонни да бъдат по-ниски в понеделник и по-високи в петък). Weirder корелации също съществува, включително hemline показател (цените са се повишили исторически и паднал в тандем с повишения и попада в средната дължина на полите на мода) и Супер купата ефект (цените са склонни да се увеличава в периода след Супер Боул, ако печеливш екип е бил член на оригиналния Националната футболна Лига, но остават по друг начин). Ефективност почитатели наричаме тези и десетки други добре известни експонати срещу ефективността на пазара "аномалии." Някои аномалии раз - появяват с течение на времето. Ефектът януари започна да направят това в средата на 1980. Когато се правят, EMT поклонници се радвам, позовавайки се на изчезват - ANCE като доказателство за ефективността на пазара. Това е странно доказателства, Въпреки това, когато се отбележи, че изчезна аномалии продължава десетилетия (седем десетилетия по отношение на ефекта януари). Още по-странен, аномалия на етикета е била прилагана за удивителен записи инвестирането на много видни stoc kpickers списък това е дълъг и получаване на по-дълго. Тя включва Бен Греъм; Уорън Бъфет; Чарли Munger, заместник-председател на Berkshire Hathaway; Джон Мейнард Кейнс; Бернар Барух; Джералд Льоб; Джон Neff на 12 Приказка за двата пазара Уиндзор фонд (Vanguard); Mario Gabelli и Дейвид Schafer; Уилям Ruane и Ричард Cuniff на Секвоя фонд; Том Кнап от Туиди Браун; Джон Темпълтън; Мейсън Хокинс на Longleaf част Нир фондове; и несметен други. Цевта на маймуни? Може ли да бъде, както EMT поклонник курорт да се каже, че това са аномалии твърде, че тези хора са просто късметлия? Може ли да се смята, правдоподобно че те са точно като на въображаем маймуна, който ще представи Целият сценарий на Хамлет от случайно удря на пишеща машина ключовете? Дори Ако сте съгласни, че това е възможно, за да завършите тезата на Imag - inary маймуна също ще трябва да бъде в състояние да удар в правилната клавиши, за да генерира пълен ръкопис на Ромео и Жулиета "," Макбет ", крал Лир, Хенри IV, както и почти целия Шекспир канон. Дори ако това е теоретично възможно, като плодовит маймуна (или барел на маймуни), изглежда невероятно. Маймуната оглед признава, че Люк kplays роля за инвестиции ING, както го прави и в други аспекти на живота. Водещата популистка апостол на този "късметлия маймуна" гледна точка е професор Принстън Бъртън Malkiel, който го обяснява в своята буу случаен Walk Down Wall Ул. "с помощта на монети несериозност contest.10 Започнете с хиляди хора несериозност монета, с тези несериозност главите са победителите и да ходи в следващия кръг. От законите на късмета, средно 500 ще флип глави и 500 ще флип опашки. В 500 несериозност глави пристъпи към кръг две, когато, пак от законите на късмета, половината ще флип глави и половина ще флип опашки. 250-щастлив главите плавници отидете на рунд, където 125 от тях победа; 63 от тези скланям четири; 31 скланям пет; 16 скланям шест; и 8 спечели финалния кръг и са обявени "експерт" монета плавници. И все пак да се прибягва до Люк Кас обяснение за инвестиции успех оставя обяснение непълни. Първо, да инвестират, просто не е като монета несериозност, въпреки че спекулации и хазарт може да бъде. Големият инвеститорите се направят някои homewor канд разработи набор от инвестиционни предварително cepts да ги насочи в избора им на инвестициите. Те не Просто обърнете монета в избора на инвестиции, за да направят. Те със сигурност не реши между, да речем, IBM и Clorox чрез поставяне техните емблеми върху монета, с образа лого за кацане до получаване на капитал. На второ място, късмет маймуна би трябвало да са чука на Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 13 ключовете всеки ден в продължение на десетилетия, много като ден търговец би трябвало да CLIC khis мишката всеки ден в продължение на десетилетия. Но големите инвеститори не последва дневно търговска стратегия. Напротив. Бъфет, например, генерирани-голямата част от милиардите на богатството Berkshire Hathaway е натрупана от около десет инвестиции за около четиридесет години. Много от тези милиарди дойде от закупуване на големи дялове в големи компании във време, когато стойността им е woefully underappreciated от пазара. Berkshire купи дела си в "Вашингтон пост" Компания за Например, в средата на 1973,11 не само че собствените stoc пост на kprice е очукан от одиране на Никсън Белия дом на своите разследващи докладване на "Уотъргейт", който беше един от малкото пъти в следвоенен Американска история, че САЩ stoc kmarket приличаше си мрачен позиция по време на Депресията. Бъфет покупната цена? За една пета на истинската стойност, 80% марж на безопасност. Люк kplays важна роля в портфейла на ден търговеца; дисциплина очевидно играе роля в Берк - Shire's. Люк KIS неадекватно макар и често частично обяснение за всяка човешки усилия, което предполага усилия. Тези, които успяват в BG - deavors улова не пеперуди от Люк kalone но с помощта на експертно хвърли мрежа. Бен Греъм обърна глоба kbetween LIN Люк канд WOR kby казва, че "един късмет, или един извънредно хитър де - cision-може да ги различавам?-може да се счита за повече от живота калфа на усилия. Но зад късмет, или решение от решаващо значение, трябва да има обикновено съществува на фона на подготовката и дисциплиниран капацитет. "12 Дали те се характеризират като стойност на инвеститорите, растеж разслед - тори, основните инвеститори, опортюнистични инвеститори, или нищо друго, CommonSense дисциплина е обединяваща черта на всички супер - инвеститори, които правят тази барел на маймуни. Вярно е, че Кейнс Льоб и са свързани с "глезен" училище за инвестиране, един опортюнистична стратегия, която бързо се експлоатира на пазара gyrations гориво от редуващи се пристъпи на страх и алчност. Техните скъсяването на хоризонта контрасти с дългосрочен мандат мнения на "стойността" училище, свързани с Гра - шунка и Бъфет, но двете училища признават цена-стойност discrep - Анси, че тези редуващи се пристъпи на биполярно разстройство, г-н пазар създадете. Всички тези инвеститори-звезден и много други, като kBogle Jac, Фил Carret, Фил Фишер, Питър Линч, цените (Майкъл и T. Rowe), и Джордж Сорос-успех при упражняването на здравия разум. В "системи" или "формули" заето или етикетите, които са им дадени 14 Приказка за двата пазара не са важни, но качеството на техния анализ и незави - симост на техните мисли и решението са. Най-добрите инвеститори се използва начин на мислене, който взема под внимание само няколко неща, но тези неща са абсолютно необходими. Всеки извънредно инвеститор следва първият принцип Бен Греъм: Пазарът не напълно цената на бизнес стойността на склад. Уорън Бъфет се прозрение, че мъртвите сериозно чрез ограничаване на покупките си за запасите, че са начин underpriced от пазара. И на тези инвестиционни титаните , както и Фил Carret подчертае значението на избягването на лоши сделки, запасите, които са надценени начин на пазара. Тези инвеститори и други велики, като партньор Бъфет Чар - лъжа Munger, винаги помнете, че има десетки хиляди инвестиционни възможности, които съществуват само за никого. За да изберат един изисква силна вяра, че пазарът е като най-добрата сделка възползва - състояние в сравнение с всички останали. И възможност е чук. Един начин да тествате възможност е да се предприемат подход Льоб's: както винаги дали ще бъде удобно извършване на голяма част от ви ресурси за един stoc Kyou обмислят. Бъфет и други видни инвеститори, включително Питър Линч, знам, че един интелигентен оценка зависи от способността ви да се по - стойка на стопанска дейност. Това ви дава основание за всички тези точки оценяваща Най-инвеститори, помисли от решаващо значение, като фирмата конкурентоспособна сила, марка сила и способност за разработване на нови продукти, изгодно. Инвестиционните гиганти (не маймуни), не се тревожи много за дали техните инвестиции до края концентрирана в определени ком - ства. Така например Джон Neff, на портфолио мениджър на Уиндзор Фонд от 1964 до 1995 г., генерирани се връща повече на AV - erage от постоянна 3% годишно и не толкова като понякога разпределяне колкото 40% от фонда в един бизнес сектор. Бъфет Berkshire Hathaway е чудесно разнообразна колекция от outstand - ING бизнеса, но това многообразие е случаен страничен продукт на безпрецедентен ръст в столицата е разположен отколкото съзнателно усилия, за да участват в много различни стопански дейности или сектори. Това хвърли на знаменит инвеститори разширява CommonSense ООН derstanding на пазарите и бизнеса за анализ на бизнес основи. Главен сред тези фактори са икономически характер - istics като силен финансово състояние, доходите и стабилност растеж, силни продажби и печалба, както и големи суми на интер - nally получени пари за финансиране на растежа в сравнение с постоянно зависимостта от външни източници на финансиране. Тези инвеститори също плащат внимание на качеството и целостта на управление, търсейки Г-н пазар биполярно разстройство 15 фирми, които системно максимизиране на пълния потенциал на предпри - ност, мъдро разпределя капитала, както и канал на ползите от този успех на акционерите. Те подчертават значението на изключително компетентни мениджъри, които притежават значителен размер на собствения капитал в собствени дружества и могат бързо да се адаптират към динамично бизнес-условия тия. Те също смятат, че управленски дълбочина и цялостност включва осигуряване на добри отношения с труда и насърчаване на предприемаческата дух. Капитана на хедж фонд Джордж Сорос го обобщи както казват по - ING, че "преобладаващите мъдрост е, че пазарите са винаги е прав, аз Предполагам, че те винаги са погрешно. "Преобладаващата мъдростта на пазара ефективност е един от начините, за да видите пазари. В този изглед, промените в цените са дължи почти изцяло на промените в основните ценности. Следователно, диверсифициран подбор на запасите с различни цени поведение Com - сравнение с общия пазар прави най-подходящ. Обратното оглед казва, че много от промените в цените се получат при nonfundamental причини. Целта тук е да се идентифицират онези компании, чиито цени са по-ниски бизнеса си стойност. Тази перспектива изисква мислене за Инди - vidual предприятията, отколкото на целия пазар. В следващите две глави предлагат алтернатива на тези фондации две конкурентни начини за тънки пазари kabout. Глава 2 е история за това как ефективно идеята на пазара се е появил. Глава 3 е сметка на доказателства, че противоречи на EMT по свой собствен начин. Ако сте вече сте скептик на ефективността на пазара, можете да пропуснете тези две глави, като практически въпрос (въпреки че те съдържат ценни прозрения по същество на конкурентните виждания). Ако сте ефективност Dev - otee, трябва да ги прочете и да бъде готов да промени мнението си. Така или иначе, глава 4 оценява сегашната среда за улики относно това дали посоката, в която ние сме позиция е по-добре описан от ефективна идея пазар или от това, което може да се нарече на "хаотичен" пазар идея. Той констатира, че ние сме позиция към по-малко отколкото по-ефективни пазари. Останалата част от куку kadopts на оглед на инвестиционните майстори, който stoc kmarkets не са напълно ефективно и осигурява на оборудването, което трябва да се възползват от липсата на ефективност. С з A P E T R 2 Прозак ПАЗАР дълга и интересна история се крие зад все по-популярни ефективно Amarket теория, история на всеки инвеститор трябва да знае. Знаейки EMT история ще ви позволи да се оцени съветите си въз основа на него, включително съвети за стойността на диверсификация и начини за измерване на риска. Тя също ще ви помогне да решите за себе си дали да вярват, EMT. Това е важно, защото, ако ти вярваш в ефективността на пазара, можете ще приеме стил и философия за инвестиране на много различен от един ти ще бъде добър да се приемат, ако не. Инвеститорите, които вече са сключили EMT, че не е най-добрият внимание на това как stoc kmarkets WOR kcould пропуснете тази глава, без да бъдат излъгани, но дори и те могат да открият начини, по които е EMT несъзнателно засегнати техните инвестиции навици. Всички читатели ще раз - покриване, че историята на EMT е очарователно. Това е история за ре - търсене за цел да увеличи знанията, за да обясни и разбере света, научните изследвания, чиито резултати са пренебрегвани и периодично след това преувеличена. Историята ни казва, че EMT не е последната дума за това как stoc kmarkets работа, въпреки че тя е имала власт над инвеститори и учители в продължение на няколко десетилетия го прави понякога изглежда, че ко - PLE тънък комплект е последният word.1 Неизвестност EMT следи историята си на случайни Wal kmodel на stoc kprices, на разумна идеята, че stoc ход kprices по начин, който не може да бъде предвиди с точност систематични. Моделът дати BAC Kto 1900 г., когато е разработен в докторска дисертация от френските математик Луис Bachelier, че макар и неясно в своето време е сега известен. Това дисертация разследвани линейна корелация в Цените на опции и фючърси, търгувани на френската борса и Con - cluded, че такива промени в цените държал в съответствие с произволни Wal model.2 17 Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc Щракнете тук за Условия за ползване 18 Приказка за двата пазара WOR Bachelier's kwas не е широко забелязал, когато беше публикуван, може би защото математически части от нея предхожда с пет години Известен WOR Айнщайн Врани на случаен принцип предложението на сблъсък газ мол - ecules. Айнщайн "открити" в уравнението, което описва Phe - феномен на случайни молекулно движение, известно като брауново движение (след шотландски ботаник Робърт Браун, който първо го наблюдава), което е точно уравнението Bachelier разработени да се опише цена поведение на финансовите пазари. Въпреки, че математически свойства Bachelier са заети на пряк и непосредствен интерес за физици и математици (включително Айнщайн и неговата интелектуална потомство), платени икономисти малко внимание на това обстоятелство до средата на века. Наистина, почти няма проучвания, преди началото на 1950 прави всяко позоваване на WOR Bachelier's Кор с теорията на случайните процеси във финансовите пазари. Морис Кендъл често се кредитира с привеждане на произволни Wal kmodel на вниманието на икономистите в началото на 1950. Бах - WOR kitself elier, обаче, не бе "открит" от икономисти, докато те попаднали в него в средата на 1950-те. Докато тършуват през библиотека, Леонард Савидж на Uni - versity на Чикаго попаднах на една малка буу kby Bachelier публикуване - установени през 1914 година. Той изпраща пощенски картички да си икономист приятели питат дали те са "да е чувал за този човек." Пол Самуелсън не може да намери библиотека буу род МИТ, но е поставям на място и след това се чете копие на Бах - elier's докторска дисертация. Само след откриването Самюелсън през 1959 г. произволни Wal kmodel стана много популярна област на научните изследвания. Дълго неизвестност Bachelier беше също се дължи на широко докладвани 1937 проучване от известния икономист Алфред Cowles заключи, че stoc kprices мръдна по предвидим начин. Това проучване затвори изследване на произволни Wal kmodel в продължение на десетилетия, докато през 1960 г. Станфорд професор Holbroo kWorking открили грешка в него. Cowles после поправена грешката, и неговият преработен проучване подкрепени случайната Wal kmodel. Простота След Самуелсън и колегите му преоткрива Bachelier, те също имаше голям късмет, че са в състояние да сбруя си прозрения на големи мащаб с появата на компютъра, възраст и широко разпространеното възползва - способността на университетите и научните основи на високоскоростни Com - Прозак пазар 19 puters. Използването на тези нови технологии в началото на 1960-те, stoc kmar - KET изследователи отиде да WOR kwith пълния смисъл на думата проучване на произволни процеси в тези пазари. Таблица на тестове Един от аспектите на разследването се състои от тестове, които корелация са били използвани за да се определи дали определени последователности данни ход до Гетер на всяка степен. В случай на stoc kprices, промени в цените на дава stoc Kare, отчетени през определен период от време-казват, редица на ден и последващ период от същата дължина. Тези SE - последствията (наречен време серия данни) се сравнява да се определи дали те се движат заедно с всяка степен, независимо дали те показват "Корелация." Сравнението се извършва под формата на корелационен коефициент, един номер, който отразява степента, в която данните са линейно отново преведени. В смисъл, времето, серия от данни е тестван за корелация с монтаж по права линия до данните и след това се изчислява този номер. Установена е корелация коефициент, равен на нула представи доказателства, че данни в серията са собственост на статистическа независимост; КР връзка коефициенти, които са близки до нулата (но не е равна на нула) показват, че данните са uncorrelated. А време серия от данни, се завтече - Дом, ако то е било независими или uncorrelated. Помислете за телевизията чертежи лотария, в която печели лотарията номера се определят като изберете номерирани топчета от бен , съдържащи множество топчета с различни номера рисувани върху тях. Одиторът извлича топка, записа си номер, и замества, че топка. Одиторът прави това може би три пъти, всеки път, извличане, запис и замяна. Този процес е собственост на статистическа независимост, тъй като броят записани след всяка извличане в dicates нищо за броя записани или преди това или под - sequently. Извън контекста на контролирана като лотария хамбар, особено в контекста на времето серия данни, като например stoc kprices, че е изключително трудно да се докаже, че редица статистически данни има свойството на статистическа независимост. Колкото по-малко рестриктивни имот-данни, че са uncorrelated-е податлива на статистически доказателства и дава възможност за заключенията съществено подобни на тези, които следват от по - зависимостта собственост. Съотношението тестове на 1960-те години на всички води в съответствие сътрудничество коефициенти, които не се различават съществено от нула. Това означаваше, че


20 Приказка за двата пазара различни серии от действителните stoc kmarket данни са неразличими от различни серии от числа, генерирани от произволен брой маса, рулетка, изготвяне лотарията, или друго устройство на шанс. Тези констатации имат важно практическо отражение: Автокъщи системно не може да направи по-нормални печалби от търговия да бъде - предизвика статистически Lac корелация KOF предполага, че най-добрата оценка на бъдещата цена на stoc KIS сегашния си цена. С други думи, ако цени следват случайна разходка, промяната в цената от един път на следващия няма да повлияе на вероятността, че дадена промяна на цените ще се следва, че един. Минали цени не може да предскаже бъдещето цени. Писти А отдавна знаят, слабост на корелация тестове е, че резултатите могат да бъдат изопачени от малък брой на извънредно заседание на данните в динамични редове. Един алтернативен тест, който избягва тази слабост е анализ на писти на данни разследване дали има някаква устойчивост към посоката на последователни промени. А тичам се определя от липсата на посока промяна в статистиката в серия. Така, нова тичам започва всяко време промени посоката (т.е., от негативна към позитивна, от положителна на отрицателна, или от непроменен с отрицателни или положителни). Вместо това на проверка на съответствието на числени промени в данни в серия, един разследва връзката на посоката на тези промени. Ако промените в цените следват произволни Wal kmodel, броя на последователности и обръщане във времето серия данни на stoc Цените ще бъдат приблизително равни. Ако една и съща посока продължава за значи - бяха съществено по-дълъг период, на случаен принцип Wal kmodel ще бъде оспорено. Сред многобройните проучвания тичам проведено в началото на 1960-те, Университета в Чикаго икономист Юджийн Фама се разглежда като най-careful.3 Фама установено, че посоката на промените в цените тенденция да продължи, но въпреки това заключение, че няма правило или търговия стратегия може да се изведе, че надминаха на пазара последователно. Съответно, почти всеки, който участва в дебата в края на 1960 се съгласиха, че наблюдават отклонения от случайността са negligi - Регистриран и вярваше, че това представлява силна подкрепа за произволни Wal kmodel. Правила за търговия с Въпреки широко съгласие, някои от участниците в дебата остана скептичен. В действителност, далновиден коментатори на онази епоха OC - Прозак пазар 21 casionally изрази опасение, че взаимоотношенията на stoc kprice промени са толкова сложни, че стандартните инструменти като те не могат да разкрият тях. Това води до страх усилия за спора на модела чрез проектиране търговски правила, които биха могли да постигнат по-нормални резултати, посредством разкриването и използването на тези по-големи усложнения. Сред най-примитивни че най-красноречивите правила търговия Сидни е Александър "филтър техника." Това е проектиран и стратегия да разпознават и да използват приема тенденции в stoc kprices, че Алекс - пикантен фраза Ander, тя може да бъде "маскиран от jiggling на мар - трудовия пазар. "4 Например, "5 правило% филтър" за stoc kwould казвам да го купя когато цената отива до 5% (и гледайте го доведат до по-висок връх), след това да го продава на цена, когато слиза, че 5% от грах к (и да го гледате спаднат до по-ниски най-ниските), след това за кратко stoc к (т.е., тя заема и продават то в преобладаващата цена, като обеща да възстанови със същия състав, за да да бъдат закупени на цени, действащи към момента на възстановяване), след това, когато повишенията на цените, че 5% от най-ниските, покриване на къси позиции. Ако това, Вие получавате печалба на първоначалната продажба плюс печалба на къса позиция. По-важно е, ако тя работи, цените са вследствие на връх-ниските модел. Това означава, че те не са случайни и се завтече - Дом Wal kmodel е оспорено. Александър Първоначалните резултати показват, че такава техника, може да производството на по-нормална възвращаемост. Следващи подобрения на Alexan - Der's WOR kby себе си и другите, включително Фама, обаче, DEM - onstrated че релаксиращи или промяна на някои предположения елиминира ненормалните се връща, особено оригиналната техника филтър не успяват - Часовници да се отбележи, че дивидентите са разходи, отколкото полза тогава, когато запаси са продадени кратко. Александър филтър техника символизира чартист или технически подход към stoc kanalysis и търговия, при които едно проучване на миналото цени (или други данни) се използва като основа за предвиждане на бъдещите цени. Всъщност, Александър филтър техника е идеен братовчед на граничните нареждания и подобни техники преобладават в търговията с ценни книжа и днес. Тези техники включват конвенционални технически методи, които разчитат аномалия на ефекти (The Insider, месец, уикенд, и EF-анализатор fects), както и по-нестандартни методи (на hemline индикатор, индикатор за Супер Боул, и т.н.). Тези и свързаните с тях философии като "инерция инвестиране" и "въртене сектор" остават Staples futurology на Уол Стрийт. Те са широко и все повече се използва от търговците и препоръчани от инвестиционни консултанти и брокери. Те са глупости, тъй като много Stu - 22 Приказка за двата пазара денти на произволни Wal kmodel (и EMT) признават въз основа на горе анализ. Те не са глупости, защото на EMT, а защото те летят в лицето на бизнес анализа. Тъй като Бен Греъм каза на поддръжниците на такива технически методи в The Intelligent Investor: "Ние трябва да отхвърли тези с наблюдението, че не им WOR kdoes загриженост "разслед - тори ", тъй като термин е използван в тази книга" 5. От своя собствена гледна точка, проблемът с всички тези тестове на завтече - Дом Wal KIS, че те са линейни. Те не се занимават с разследване на присъствие на нелинейни цена зависимост, нещо, което в началото на 1960 изследователи просто липсва конски сили компютър, за да направя. Тестът търговия правило, например, е линейна с това, че работи в хронологичен време (или в реално време). Нито той, нито на други стари тестове обмислиш възможността, че на пазара време може да бъде по-добре разбрани от гледна точка на това е нелинейна. Ние ще стигнем до тази тема следващата глава, но за сега се отбележи, че Айнщайн показа, че време не е абсолютна, но работи в десетки различни начини в зависимост от контекста, в това число напред (или линейни), назад, кръгли, бавно и хаотично (нелинейни), и дори може да стои на едно място. НА PERFEC TDREAM Много хора предполагат, че EMT разработени по своеобразен начин в научни изследвания. В доказателство на хипотезата, е първо, началото с Bachelier през 1900 г. и осъществява чрез богатството на проучвания докладване случайността в началото на 1960. Само тогава е планирана теория да обясни случайността, започва с първото обяснение на EMT през 1965 г. от Пол Са - muelson, получател на Нобелова награда за икономика през 1970,6 Икон - omists приветства това доказателство. Условията, необходими за създаването му изглеждаше tantalizingly близки до тези, необходими за поддържане на всеки попу - omist's Dream: идеалното пазар. Идеалният пазар е евристичен изобретен от вземане на последващи ING предположения относно пазара: Има голям брой Участниците са такива, че действията на всеки отделен участник може да - не се отрази на пазара; участници са напълно информирани, са равен достъп до пазара и да действат рационално, а стоката е хомогенни, и там не са транзакционните разходи. Перфектно пазар ще ви даде точно това, на случаен принцип Wal Прозак пазар 23 модел предполага: Цените на акциите в stoc kmarkets следва да преизчислят мигновено и точно на нова информация във връзка с тях. Тази прогноза е въплътена в EMT, тъй като за първи път изнася. В най-широкия условия, EMT каза, че цените на акции, търгувани в stoc kmarkets напълно отразяват цялата информация, свързани с тези акции. Stoc kmarkets може или не може да имат характеристиките приема от перфектния модел на пазара. Тъй като от 1976 г. лауреат на Нобелова награда Милтън Фридман ни напомня, обаче, че кардинал върховенството на преден план-икономически кастинг е, че предсказуем мощност на модел е от значение само тест за нейната валидност, а не на предположения основните it.7 Така, фактът, че инвеститори не са рационални или напълно информиран, например, не значение, доколкото тези реалности не са в противоречие с предсказуем Силата на EMT. Въпреки че много икономисти са преразглеждане на предположения, тия като тези, за сега този подход има власт над любимци икономическа теория. Три форми на ефективност По принцип си форма, EMT обяснява повече от случаен Wal модел. Този модел се казва просто, че няколко последователни промени в цените са независими или uncorrelated, докато EMT обяснява, че чрез изричане че stoc kprices напълно отразяват цялата информация (не само цената си - лаборатории) за един състав. В резултат на това, на практика, тъй като появата на EMT като обяснение на произволни Wal kmodel, EMT е разделени в три форми, определени по отношение на определени категории информация. Трите форми са били предложен за първи път за класифициране на емпирични изследвания на цена поведение дава определени видове информация. В WEA kform изпитан произволни Wal kmodel себе си, като се използва съответствието и тичам тестове като тези, които просто е описано да се проучи дали последните цени показват, нищо за бъдещите цени. Semistrong форма тестване разследвани дали публично достъпна информация, различни от цените е ре - flected в преобладаващите цени, тестване и силна форма разследвани независимо дали са частни информация е отразена в преобладаващите цени. Тъй като богатство на тестове и дискусията продължи през 1970-те, трите форми на EMT започва да се използва за обозначаване на заключенията тези тестове появяват. По този начин, формите на EMT оттогава е определени, както следва: WEA kform казва, че stoc kprices отразява напълно цялата информация, състояща се от миналото цени, казва semistrong форма че stoc kprices напълно отразяват цялата информация, която в момента е публично 24 Приказка за двата пазара на разположение, както и силната форма (задръжте дъха си) се казва, че stoc цените отразява напълно всички съществуващи информация, независимо дали публично достъпни или не. Там е по този начин пряко и логично LIN kbetween случайната Wal модел и слаба ефективност форма, но по-отслабени и продължа - Гент LIN kbetween Wal kmodel на случаен принцип и по-силни форми на EMT. Спомнете си, че случайната Wal kmodel смята, че промените в цените са независими или uncorrelated с предварително промени в цените. Онзи означава, че техническият анализ на последните промени в цените-понякога наречен чартист анализ-жаргон помощ за предсказване на бъдещето цена промени във всеки систематичен начин. Слаба форма ефективност обяснява тази независимост и водните клетъчни канали при - катиони за прогнозиране от hypothesizing, че сегашната цена IM - лири цялата информация, съдържаща се в предварително цени. Така, на всяка цена промяна може да бъде само резултат на нова информация, производство на която се приема за себе си произволно. Този процес на информация абсорбция продължава и по този начин обяснява липсата на значителни линейна зависимост при последващи промени в цените открити в КР връзка и прави изследвания на 1960-те години. Това също води до по-силните форми на хипотеза. В semistrong формата на EMT постулира, че не само текущите stoc цените отразяват цялата информация, състояща се от предварително stoc kprices, но също така , че те отразяват всички публично достъпна информация за stoc род въпрос. Извършваща това изисква по-амбициозни иск не се фокусира върху корелационен анализ на ценовите промени, но по отношение на относителния бързина , с която цените промяна дава нова информация. Въпреки това различни методика на изпитване, semistrong ефективност зависи от валидността на произволни Wal kmodel, която зависи от на свой ред на емпирични заключения по отношение на липсата на стати - tical в зависимост stoc kprice данни. С други думи, ако бъдещата цена промени зависят от преди промени в цените, всяка промяна на цената, на полу - тестове силна форма не може да се дължи единствено на новите инфор - информация за изпитване е оценката. Така, както WEA kefficiency и полу - силна ефективност зависи от доказателства, предоставени от линейни тестване модели. Силната форма на EMT простира много по-далеч от случайни Wal kmodel появяват. В действителност, силна форма е богословски предложение - osition, считайки, че публичните капиталови пазари са безкрайно мъдър дори непублична информация се отразява в обществените stoc kprices. Abundant доказателства decimated силната форма, като демонстрира, че хората, които притежават непублична информация може да го използвате, за да направи ненормално високи Прозак пазар 25 се връща на пазара, с апотеоз на търговия с вътрешна информация се сканиране dals на 1980г. Тъй като силна форма на EMT е компрометирано, дебати Con - подробни данни центрове EMT на semistrong и kforms WEA. Дебат над WEA kform обикновено се определя чрез анализ на произволни Wal kmodel себе си, обикновено в условията на линейни емпирични модела използва за тестване на връзката между последователни промени в цените, това намали в произволни Wal kmodel. Широко отбележи, проучване на Андрю Ло MIT's и А. Wharton's Крейг MacKinlay демонстрира силна положителна корелация в сериен stoc kprices за седмичен и месечен период на държане се връща. Използване 1216 седмично stoc kreturn наблюдения от 1962 до 1985 г., те са установили седмична корелационният коефициент от 30%, което е изключително високо ниво на корелация. Тези изследователи посочват в книгата си ", не - Случайни Walk Down Wall Street, че това не означава непременно че stoc kmarket е неефективно, но че произволното Wal kmodel не може да бъде основа за теорията на efficiency.8 Макар и да не убедителни доказателства, като това доведе дори Евгений Фама-главен архитект на EMT-до извода, че дневни и седмични stoc kreturns са предвидими от последните данни, като по този начин се отхвърля произволни Wal kmodel на статистическа basis.9 Дори и така, и Фама други бащите на EMT придържам към мнението, че тези различия са аномалии, че просто не нарушават валидност на основния модела, въпреки че други се опитват да обяснят тези резултати по различен начин, наречен шум. Шум Помислете добре Джон Мейнард Кейнс's известни мета-конкурс за красота phor за stoc kmarket. В конкурса, всеки съдия може да мотика на - кандидатки той или тя мисли, че другите ще PIC krather от кандидат той или тя мисли, че трябва да спечелим по заслуги. Тя замества основно или подреди по същество на анализ (от вида, призова в тази книга), с популярен, спекулативен, и стадото-Pac kmentality. От 1981 г. лауреат на Нобелова награда Джеймс Тобин на Йейл твърде kKeynes's конкурс за красота една стъпка по-далеч. Той предложи дори ако обществена капиталовия пазар е ефективно, в смисъл на бързо, включващи публични информация в stoc kprices (т.е. semistrong под формата на EMT), това не означава непременно, че stoc kprices на този пазар отново flect основните ценности (т.е. настоящата стойност на очакваните бъдещи потоци към акционерите) .10 26 Приказка за двата пазара Качеството на информацията усвоява от пазара може да бъде само толкова ниски, колкото на качеството на информацията, която отива в решенията на Кейнс's съдии конкурс за красота. Тобин има много последователи, които тънки той е прав, включително носителите на Нобелова награда Уилям Ф. Шарп и Кен - Neth стрелката на Stanford.11 Ако това е вярно, че много търговци действа като Кейнс описани, semistrong формата на EMT трябва да се подразделят между строгия информационен ефективност и по-рафинирани Понятието основните ефективност. Информационен ефективност описва пазар, на който всички обществени информация за stoc KIS отразена в цената на този stoc kwith - посочени отношение на качеството на тази информация. По този начин, информацията, която се отнася до фундаменталната стойност на stoc KIS отразени, но това е информация изцяло е свързана с тази основна ценност, като например, които спечели Супер Боул. Основни ефективност е по-тесен, но по-амбициозна идея, че stoc kprices са точни индикатори за по - trinsic стойност, тъй като те отразяват само информация, отнасяща се забавни damental бизнес values.12 Въпросът дали става на капиталовите пазари, могат да различат сред видове информация, така че само информация за основните - умствени стойност е задържани и са отразени в цените. Това съживява Основният въпрос дали хората се държат рационално. EMT казва, че няма значение, ако на отделните действия, които не са рационални, тъй като всяка индивидуален ирационалност ще бъдат коригирани от други действащи рационално. В смисъл, неразумно е "се приема" на модела EMT. В информационно-фундаментална разлика, обаче, е толкова intu - itively и емпирично мощен, че е трябвало да се сблъскат. В резултат на бе лице за спестяване на подслон на евфемизъм: The Economist Фишер Черно заеми, термин от областта на статистиката, преименуван Ирра - tional поведението на шум, което би позволило уважаващ себе си икономист за да обсъждане на проблема и се опитват да модел it.13 Шум теория се подкрепя от значителни емпирични доказателства и добре развита интелектуална основа. Шум теория модели притежават stoc kmarkets, че са заразени със значителен обем на търговия въз основа на информация, свързана с основните ценности на активите (шум търговия). Тези модели се опита да обясни защо и двете шум търговия се случи и защо неговите последици продължават. Най-честият модел шум теория казва, например, че шум се извършва търговия с зле информирани инвеститори, които действат на сен - timent отколкото рационален анализ. Техните действия ход цени далеч от основните ценности. Цената стойност на разликата продължава да съществува, въпреки присъствието на сложна arbitrageurs, защото те са рискови-неблагоприятният Прозак пазар 27 и не могат да бъдат сигурни, че настроения на инвеститорите няма да се промени неблагоприятно по всяко time.14 Доказателство за шумни подход за инвеститорите на stoc kmarket в cludes следните съвети или действащи от слухове, бързо се превръща над нечии портфейл, продажба на добри изпълнители като същевременно запазва лошите (по този начин-стегнат Gering облагаемата печалба, отколкото генериране на данък се приспада загуби), разплащателни огромен взаимен фонд такси за бедните управленски резултати, и имитиращи други в движение на разстояние от пазара на скалите, като използвате глупав технически търговски стратегии. Причините за това поведение остават недобре разбрана, но Psy - chological изследвания се предполага, няколко тенденции. Тези tenden - тики включва отношението към RIS kthat хора да доведе до по-неблагоприятният до загуба от желание за печалба; това обяснява ирационални тенденция към задръжте, докато запасите губи продажба печели запаси. Друг е изопачаване вероятностите на несигурни бъдещи събития от базира на прогнозите последните модели, като и прогнозира, че приходите растеж през следващите десет години ще е равно на това на последните три. На теория, умни arbitrageurs пари може да коригира всички тези грешки и печалбата от тях, поддържане EMT непокътнати. Но това е рисковано предпри - ност. Ако има mispricing днес, може да има mispricing утре. Ако запасите се цени високо в сравнение със стойност, една arbitrageur ще се продава кратко и очакват корекцията. Но корекцията не може да пристигне преди тя да покрие. Ако запасите са скромните цени, в сравнение със стойност, АРБ ще купя една и очакват възход. Но тази поправка може да е под дълго време, през което тези средства могат да бъдат изпратени на по-високи се връща на друго място. Друга възможност е, че отделни дейности, които могат да са рационални производство на обединяване на резултатите, които са ирационални. Това се случва на всички време в бизнеса. След климатик е измислена, например, магазини изразходвани значителни суми, за да го инсталирате, но веднъж на всеки магазин е това, никой от тях не получи конкурентно предимство като резултат. Това е причината да видите бензиностанция на всеки ъгъл на крайградски на интер - раздел. Бъфет дава пример за това какво се случва, когато всеки човек гледането на парада той решава или тя може да видите малко по-добре с готовност ING на пръсти. Въпреки тези дълбоки прозрения, разработени на границите на мислех за това как пазарите, те продължават да бъдат третирани като много водещи икономисти като вариации на тема. Може би там известно отклонение в EMT, поклонник си призная, но отклоненията са поради Неслучайно. Юджийн Фама, например, продължава да се спори overreaction видно, че до информация е също толкова често, колкото ап - 28 Приказка за двата пазара майка underreaction до информация, както и вероятността за абнормна се връща продължава след събитието, са почти толкова вероятно като се връща заден след това събитие. Така, цяла група от водещи икономисти смята, че най-новите доказателства срещу EMT не добавите до много. Те придържам към по - одежда инструменти, които се основават на EMT и използвани за допълване на теоретична картина с практически приложения. Почистване ПРИКАЗКА EMT ни казва, че определени определя информация са напълно отразени в цената на публични ценни книжа. EMT, обаче, не предоставя никаква основа за определяне на това какво означава за всяка подобна информация да бъде напълно отразени в stoc kprices. Правейки това изисква една теория на активите ценообразуване. Тя се състои от две популярни идеи: модерно портфолио теория, , който предоставя на фондацията, както и капиталът модел актив ценообразуване, , която е обща парадигма. Модерни Портфолио Теория Докато произволни Wal kmodel и EMT са били разработени в 1950-те и 1960-те, Хари Markowitz на Сити Юнивърсити в Ню Yor канд още един Нобелов лауреат (през 1990 г., заедно с Шарп) се развива съвременната теория на портфейла (MPT) .15 Основната Идеята тук е, че съчетава група noncorrelated запаси в единични резултата от портфейла в портфейл с по-малко от нестабилността на AV - erage колебанията на тези индивидуални акции. MPT предлага, че всички инвестиции са сведени до две еле - менти-RIS канд връщане и предполага, че инвеститорите са риска Аверс в смисъл, че те ще се връща жертва за да се избегне RIS канд търсене по-голяма възвращаемост да поемат риск. MPT казва, че такива инвеститори ще най-добре на техните RIS kaversion като инвестират в портфейл от инвестиции менти, в които те получават най-очакваната възвръщаемост за всеки определено ниво на риск. Очакваната възвръщаемост на инвестицията е просто претеглената средната стойност на всички възможни връща на нея, и RIS KOF инвестиция е възможно разпространението на възвращаемостта на инвестициите, че около очакваната възвръщаемост. Под MPT, очакваната възвръщаемост на портфейла на по - одежди е просто претеглената сума от очакваните отчети за индивидуални инвестиции, като рискът, обаче, на портфейл от инвестиции Прозак пазар 29 менти не е задължително претеглената сума от рискове (или дисперсия в доходността) на отделните инвестиции. Централният прозрение на MPT е, че тъй като разликите в ре - се превръща в индивидуални инвестиции може да се намали разпространението на връща на портфейл от инвестиции, портфолио RIS KIS предимно функцията на степента на различие в индивидуални инвестиции в сравнение с портфейла като цяло. Това означава, че портфейл RIS KIS сведена до минимум чрез диверсификация на портфейла. MPT разбиране на РИС khas друг важен последствия. По отношение на всяка състав, два елемента на речни информационни услуги kcan бъдат разграничени RIS канд несистематичен систематичен риск. Системно RIS к (също част - пъти наречен пазар RIS Кор undiversifiable на риска) възниква от десет dency на stoc Кой варира, тъй като на пазар, на който се търгува тя варира. Несистематичен RIS к (понякога се нарича уникален риск, остатъчния риск, специфичен риск, или diversifiable риск) произтича от особеностите на специално stoc kbeing разследвани. Тъй като съгласно Директива диверсификация MPT's несистематичен риск могат да бъдат диверсифицирани далеч до нула, се връща на пазара на stoc род едно Com - конкурентни на пазара няма да включва никакви компенсации за такъв риск. По този начин, се връща на пазара ще бъде функция само на систематичен риск, или степента, в която специално stoc kvaries, тъй като пазарът на която е част варира. Измерване на RIS канд връщане е основният Целта на капиталовите активи модели за ценообразуване. The Capital Асет Ценови модел Както и MPT EMT са зреене в края на 1960, капиталови активи ценообразуване теория е в начален стадий. Капиталът модел на активите ценообразуване (CAPM), която е най-широко известни днес произтича от MPT (и Беше много много измислена от съвместно Markowitz's-Nobelist, Шарп) .16 Както MPT, CAPM предполага, че инвеститорите са риска Аверс, в смисъл що описах. В допълнение, CAPM предполага, че инвеститорите са RA - tional очаквания относно очакваните резултати. В рамките на тази предположения, TION, CAPM казва, че очакваната възвръщаемост на инвестицията е равен на безрисков лихвен процент на възвращаемост, както и обезщетение за системно RIS KOF инвестицията в смисъл, що описах. Систематичното KIS RIS измерва чрез степента на изменчивост на отделните инвестиции спрямо пазара като цяло. Той се отнася kpremium на речни информационни услуги, свързани с конкретен stoc к (неговото връщане, по-малко безрисков връщане) на този, свързани с пазара като цяло. Тази асоциация за stoc KIS, изразена от редица нарича 30 Приказка за двата пазара на фондовата's? (бета). Под CAPM, запасите с по-високи? Е по - рисковано, отколкото са с по-ниски запаси? е, защото те са склонни към по-люлка широко, отколкото на пазара им се връща проявяват по-голяма дисперсия спрямо пазара се връща. Критика и здравия разум На свой собствен начин, има няколко слабости в MPT и CAPM. Първо, при оценяване на EMT, необходимостта за CRE модел на ценообразуване - Атес съвместна проблем хипотеза: Никой не винаги могат да бъдат сигурни в тестването модел дали пропускът се дължи на неефективността на пазара или на недостатъчно определен модел на активите ценообразуване. В действителност, много от аномалии в EMT споменах по-рано са дължи на недостатъци в модела на активите цени, отколкото да присъствие на пазара неефективност. Тези пропуски са най - десет свързани с неточност при определянето на RIS Kor, което е същото, в посочва?. Общият проблем хипотеза има важно отражение върху EMT скептици. За да опровергае EMT изисква доказателство, че не използва модел на активите на цените. Въпреки това, всяка линейни или нелинейни зависимост в stoc kprice поведение е в противоречие с EMT себе си. Така, раз - covery на линейни или нелинейни зависимостта на последователни stoc kprices (представена в следващата глава) означава EMT е непълна, период. Тя не позволява на алтернативно обяснение на "misspecified" Асет модел на ценообразуване. В допълнение, CAPM казва, че очаква се връща от инвестиции среда са линейно свързани с очаква възвръщаемост на портфейла на тази инвестиция, която е част. На линейна връзка е дадено от ? и на свой ред е продиктувано от рационално-CAPM очаквания предположения, TION. Ако човешкото поведение също е в противоречие с рационално - очакванията предположение, че няма причина да вярвам в такова линейна връзка. Това е друг начин да се каже, че stoc kmar - KET е нелинейна, а не линейна. В този случай? няма да бъде точна мярка на риска. И накрая, рационални очаквания предположението, използвани в CAPM изисква, че инвеститорите са хомогенни очакванията за връщане; това от своя страна предполага, че инвеститорите оценяват и разбират информация от един и същи начин. Героичният да звучи, то също така ще изисква от всички инвеститорите да оценяват възможностите за инвестиции по време идентичен


Prozac Market 31

horizons. The patent dubiousness of these requirements recently has
become an important aspect of the literature criticizing CAPM.
The literature demonstrates that demand for particular stocks is
sensitive to price changes, just like demand for most other goods.17
Investors have different appetites for particular stocks as their prices
change. Thus, markets do not depict the right price of a stoc kbe-
cause there is no such thing. Even rational people are not homo-
geneous automatons; they interpret information differently, and their
judgment about the present value of a business’s future cash flows
will vary even if they are all rational.
As Francis Fukuyama has pointed out in another context, the
neoclassical economic model of rational self-interested behavior with
which EMT is ultimately linked is right only about 80% of the time.18
Its devotees forget Adam Smith, the father of their thought, who
emphasized that economic life is embedded in social life and that
economic actors make decisions that vary from pure economic cal-
culus as a result of social habits and contexts. That is why in Smith’s
day his field was called “political economy” rather than, as it is today,
simply “economics.”
If the rest of social science should be returned to economics, it
is even possible to add some physics from the hard sciences. Recall
that the random wal kmodel got that name because public capital
markets seemed to obey the principles of Brownian motion, which
specify that molecules in motion behave randomly. Although mole-
cules lac ksentience, prices are strictly creatures of the ultimate sen-
tience, human behavior.
Common sense thus suggests that the price-molecule parallel
should not hold. More powerfully, current thought in physics con-
cerning nonlinear dynamics and chaos theory extends well beyond
Brownian motion and suggests further reasons to doubt and recon-
sider the validity of the analogy.
The next chapter shows how that analogy has been turned upside
down and inside out. Before going on, though, pause to consider
whether common sense supports ? as a measure of risk. What ?
really measures is the price volatility of a stock. If you insist on
associating the word “risk” with that measure, it at most means that
? captures the ris kof stoc kprice gyrations. For a market analyst,
that measurement may be of some interest.
But for a business analyst, price gyrations are useless analytic
tools, and so therefore is ?. What matters in business analysis might
be called “business volatility,” the gyrations in earnings or cash flows


32 A Tale of Two Markets

a business has experienced as grounds for gauging its future business
performance. The earnings and cash flows are what give a business
value and what are of interest; market prices do not, and ? is
therefore of no interest to a business analyst.
As the vogue of mathematical investing approaches raged in the
late 1960s, Ben Graham declared that treating volatility in price
changes as the meaning of ris kis “more harmful than useful for
sound investment decisions because it places too much emphasis on
market fluctuations.”19 EMT sought to neutralize that objection by
saying that market fluctuations were simply rational price changes
reflecting information changes. Just so. Yet some things are not that
simple. Charlie Munger is fond of quoting Einstein on this point:
Everything should be made as simple as possible, but no more so.20
Graham continues to be right.


C h a p t e r 3

CHAOTIC MARKET

oday’s investor can learn something from the elite group of No-
Tbel Prize winners who brought us the “modern finance” sum-
marized in the last chapter, but way less than is commonly believed.
Although few informed students of EMT ever had great confidence
in the strong form, the more modest forms—plus modern portfolio
theory and beta (?)—have held sway over academic and popular
investment thinking for nearly three decades.
Those hypotheses are based exclusively on simple linear analysis
and thought, however, and so their descriptive power and normative
implications are questionable. As in all fields of endeavor, knowledge
continues to advance. Technology has enabled better ways to model
market behavior than were available when EMT and the rest of mod-
ern finance were growing up. The new technology shows quite dif-
ferent results than did the old, results that confirm the common-
sense intuitions behind Ben Graham’s Mr. Market.1

NEW WAVE

The presence of noise in stoc kmarket trading shows the inadequacy
of the linear testing models that led to the random wal kmodel and
EMT. Noise theory shows that the information-processing properties
of public capital markets are so bluntly powerful that fundamental
information about underlying business values is crowded out by ex-
traneous information or noise. There is a feedbac ksystem in which
individuals overreact to information or withhold action in the face
of information.
Feedbac kprocesses are the hallmarks of a nonlinear system.
They indicate a nonproportional relationship between a cause and
its effect (e.g., between news and price changes). This insight of
noise theory has not been recognized for its full power. The distinc-
tion between linear and nonlinear is fundamental to an understand-

33

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


34 A Tale of Two Markets

ing of stoc kmarket behavior and how investors and managers should
thin kabout markets and market prices.
Linearity means proportionality: A change in one variable pro-
duces a proportionate change in another specified variable. What
makes the CAPM linear, for example, is its assertion that the ex-
pected ris kpremium of a stoc kvaries in direct proportion to ?.
EMT is linear in two ways. First, the statistical models under-
lying the wea kform are simple linear regression analyses; correlation
coefficients are statements about how variables are related on a
straight-line basis over time. In other words, the time series of data
is tested for correlation by fitting a straight line to the data and then
calculating the correlation coefficient.
Second, the semistrong form of EMT is linear because it defines
a proportional relationship between information changes and price
changes. In particular, the semistrong form says that information is
swiftly incorporated into prices without bias. In other words, there
is a proportional relationship between information changes about
business values and resulting price changes in the financial asset
(stocks) representing those businesses.
In contrast and a bit simplistically, nonlinearity means the ab-
sence of proportionality: Changes in one variable will produce a
change in another variable, but exponentially rather than propor-
tionally. To take a prosaic example, the 1-gram straw that breaks the
1-ton camel’s bac kis nonlinear because the cause is utterly dispro-
portionate to the effect.
Volatile stoc kprices and roaring or crashing markets are often
attributable to an incremental bit of information piled on top of
cumulated bits of information. If one company announces that its
earnings aren’t going to be as strong as people had hoped, its stoc
price may take a haircut, but the market overall may not blush. But
as the weeks go by and a few more companies in that sector say the
same thing, Wall Street gets rattled. The shares of all the stocks in
that sector can suddenly get punished, and the pounding can spread
across the market as a whole. At some point, the creepy Wall Street
saying that there is never only one cockroach starts to resonate.
The fact that the market may react slowly or may overreact to
bits of new information is of course what noise theory teaches and
explains. The distinction between nonlinear and linear systems goes
well beyond noise theory, however, because noise theory itself is con-
strained by the efficiency paradigm. Nonlinear dynamics and chaos
theory brea kfrom that context and imply a fundamentally different


Chaotic Market 35

understanding of public capital market phenomena with a broader
perspective on investor and market behavior.
There is no a priori reason to believe that public capital markets
are linear systems rather than nonlinear systems. Therefore, one of
the first questions that must be considered in understanding such
markets is whether they follow linear or nonlinear processes. More
sophisticated techniques than were available when the random wal
model was first developed are now used to investigate precisely that
question.
One reason such techniques were unavailable in the 1960s,
1970s, and even early 1980s was the need for powerful computer
systems that not only could process data more swiftly but also could
go beyond the simplified mathematical models of straight lines and
investigate the curvatures of multidimensional data streams. Armed
with such resources, researchers now start with the consensus view
that empirical research shows that a random wal kdescribes stoc
prices fairly well, subject to some anomalies. Then they dig deeper.
One tool for the digging actually dates to the early part of the
twentieth century. It was developed by the hydrologist H. E. Hurst
when he was working on the Nile River Dam project.2 Hurst had to
develop reservoir discharge policies to maintain reservoir water levels
in the light of rainfall patterns.
To understand how the reservoir system worked, Hurst would
record its water level each day at noon and calculate the range (es-
sentially differences between the high and low levels and the average
levels). If the range increased in proportion to the number of ob-
servations recorded, one could conclude that the reservoir system
was a random one. Otherwise, it was nonrandom and exhibited some
pattern, knowing either of which could enable the hydrologist to set
the reservoir’s discharge policies.
Hurst developed a simple tool called the H exponent to deter-
mine whether the range increased as would a random process or
whether it exhibited a more patterned behavior. Skipping the math-
ematical details, if a system’s H equals .50, then the system behaves
according to a random walk. The probability that any particular move
will follow any other move is 50-50 and thus completely up to
chance.
If H is less than .50, the system is mean reverting. That means
that if the system has moved up for a number of observations, it is
more likely to move down over the next number of observations, and
vice versa. Conversely, if H is greater than .50, the system is correl-


36 A Tale of Two Markets

ative or persistent: if the system has moved up for a number of
observations, it is more likely to continue to move up over the next
number of observations, and vice versa. If H is .60, for example, the
probability that a positive move will follow a positive move is 60%.
H may change over time. For example, H may be in the .70s over
some period and then drop to near .50 and subsequently increase
again. The number of observations (or time periods) over which H
is sustained at other than .50 (before returning to near .50) is a
measure of the average cycle length of the system.
In the case where H exceeds .50 for a sustained period, the
length of that period is a measure of the system’s memory—the ex-
tent to which past events influence present and future events. In
the context of investment analysis, it measures the period over which
an investor can use information to his or her advantage.
During the 1990s, some market analysts figured out that the H
exponent can also be applied to markets to determine whether they
are random too. One of them even published his results. Edgar Pe-
ters, a money manager in Boston, applied it to the Standard and
Poor’s 500 Index (the S&P 500) for monthly data over a 38-year
period from January 1950 through July 1988.3
Peters found that H was .78 for average periods of approximately
four years, indicating a strong persistent element in the S&P 500
rather than a random process. Beyond average periods of four years,
however, H was not significantly different from .50 (it was .52/-.02).
So Peters concluded that the S&P 500 begins to lose memory of
events after four years. The S&P 500 thus is not random, and events
today continue to affect price changes for up to an average of four
years.

NEX TWAVE

This dashing of the economist’s dream of a perfect market has been
amplified by studies of the chaotic behavior of markets. Just as
Hurst’s H suggests that markets are not linear as EMT assumes,
EMT’s assumption of market rationality is put into scientific doubt
by principles first developed by physicists in the field of chaos theory.
Chaos theory was popularized by the publication of James
Gleick’s 1987 best-selling boo Chaos, primarily an exposition of
chaos in natural science. The potential role of chaos theory in eco-
nomics and finance was made prominent by the Santa Fe Institute’s


Chaotic Market 37

publication of a volume in 1988. It has been carried into the realm
of “phynance”—the merger of physics and finance—most spectac-
ularly by Doyne Farmer and Norman Packard, whose phynance ex-
ploits are chronicled by Thomas Bass in his 1999 boo The Predic-
tors. As a result of these works, chaos theory became an important
and growing field in the study of the nonlinear dynamic behavior of
economic and financial systems.
Through chaos theory, physicists discovered that many phenom-
ena in the universe previously thought to be random (unpredictable,
exhibiting no pattern) are not random but exhibit a significant pat-
tern. To oversimplify, chaos theory holds that there is a pattern to
the seeming randomness of physical events occurring in the uni-
verse. Thus, systems that appear to be stochastic (to involve only
random motion or behavior under conventional linear modeling)
may be deterministic, or exhibit more complex internal dependence
than simple linear modeling reveals.
Chaos theory has its roots in the nineteenth-century wor kof
Henri Poincare', a French mathematician and physicist who studied
the famous three-body problem.4 Newton, using his laws of motion
and gravitation, proved that it was possible to calculate accurately
the future positions and velocities of two mutually attractive material
bodies. Neither Newton nor anyone since, however, has been able
to do so for three or more bodies.
This three-body problem reveals itself repeatedly to scientists
sending space probes to Mars and other planets: They chart a course
directed to where the planet will be in its orbit when the probe
arrives (not where the planet is upon sending the probe), but mid-
course corrections are nevertheless necessary because Newtonian
physics can predict accurately only the interaction of two bodies, not
three. (This has led some probes to be lost in space.)
Poincare' attributed the three-body problem to nonlinearities in-
herent in multibody systems as the result of which “small differences
in the initial conditions produce very great ones in the final phe-
nomena. A small error in the former will produce an enormous error
in the latter.” This insight, now the unifying core of chaos theory, is
known as “sensitive dependence upon initial conditions.”
The classic example of sensitivity to initial conditions is the but-
terfly effect in meteorology. Its pioneer in the early 1960s was the
MIT meteorologist Edward Lorenz, who said, “The dynamical equa-
tions governing the weather are so sensitive to the initial data that
whether or not a butterfly flaps its wings in one part of the world


38 A Tale of Two Markets

may make the difference between a tornado occurring or not occur-
ring in another part of the world.”5
Picture an empty hockey rink. A person places a puc kat midice
and then rolls it toward the far end of the rink. He measures the
angle of his hit, the angle of the puck’s impact, and the angle of its
rebound. He keeps measuring the puck’s angles of impact and re-
bound as the puc kbounces around the rink.
Assuming no friction, a rule of puc kmotion in the rin kis that
it will emerge from impacting a side of the rin kat precisely its angle
of approach (a similar thing will be familiar to anyone who has
played billiards). That rule means we have defined a deterministic
system under which the future position of the puc kat any time can
be forecast perfectly (assuming its actual or average speed is known).
But now assume that the initial position of the puc kis varied by
a few degrees, even an infinitesimally small variation, not observed
by or known to the forecaster. The forecaster’s predictions of the
puck’s location after it hits the first one or two sides may be impre-
cise—off by some small amount—but the imprecision will be neg-
ligible. The amount of error will grow exponentially, however, with
each subsequent impact. In a short time the forecast will be wide of
the mark.
Disturbing the measure of the puck’s initial position causes its
movement to appear random and unpredictable, whereas knowing
that measure enables precise prediction. It is this sensitive depen-
dence on initial conditions that is the signal characteristic of chaotic
systems.6 To detect its presence, Lorenz and his followers developed
a couple of fascinating tools.

Pictures and Attractors

Time-series data are conventionally plotted using simple Cartesian
geometry. For example, to plot a time series of a stock’s price, price
is plotted on the vertical axis and chronological time is plotted on
the horizontal axis.
In physics, the usual Cartesian graphs can be turned into more
powerful pictures called phase portraits plotted in phase space, a
presentation that can depict the full range of possibilities for a sys-
tem. The pendulum is the paradigm for illustrating the differences
between Cartesian plots of time-series data and phase portraits of
the same data as well as for introducing the notion of the attractor.
Consider a regularly swinging pendulum driven by mechanical


Chaotic Market 39

FIGURE 3-1 Driven pendulum time series.

force. It will swing bac kand forth at a steady speed and not come
to rest (unless we withdraw its force). A Cartesian time-series plot
would show such a pendulum’s motion as a wavy up-and-down line
whose height remains the same as time passes, as shown in Figure
3-1.7
The driven pendulum’s portrait in phase space can be envisioned
as a rectangle. At any moment in phase space, the pendulum’s angle
would dictate the location of a point horizontally and the pendulum’s
speed would dictate the location of a point vertically. As such, the
pendulum’s portrait in phase space would form a loop, illustrating
the pendulum’s continual motion through the same sequence of po-
sitions repeatedly, as shown in Figure 3-2. That continual repetition
is described as a limit cycle or a limit cycle attractor because the
pendulum (which can be called a system) is attracted to that one
and only (limit) cycle.
Now consider a pendulum undriven by permanent mechanical
force, having instead been started manually by lifting it to one end
of its orbit and letting it go. Without the permanent mechanical
force, the undriven pendulum will swing bac kand forth, gradually
reducing speed and coming closer and closer to rest. A Cartesian
time-series plot of this undriven pendulum would begin with the
same wavy up-and-down line depicting the driven pendulum just


40 A Tale of Two Markets

FIGURE 3-2 Driven pendulum phase space: ‘‘limit cycle at-
tractor.’’

described, but this line’s height would fall gradually and continu-
ously as the pendulum’s speed declined, as shown in Figure 3-3.
This pendulum’s portrait in phase space also would begin as if
it might form a loop, but owing to its declining speed, the plot would
begin to spiral inward continuously as the pendulum slowed down.
Correspondingly, the plot would converge to the origin, as shown in
Figure 3-4. The origin in this case is described as a point attractor
because the pendulum (or system) is attracted to that one and only
point.
Another way to approach the pictures is to conceive of the phase
space as a sideways view of the Cartesian time-series plot. It is in
effect a collapsed side view of the gyrations of the simple time-series
graph.
Keep that picture in mind as you consider a third type of attrac-
tor, which physicists call the strange attractor. The strange attractor
describes a system whose phase portrait will be neither a loop nor a
spiraling circle but instead will show some orbits that appear to be
random: They do not repeat and are not periodic. They are, however,
limited in range. In other words, the portrait will exist in a finite
space but will admit of an infinite number of solutions in that finite
space.


FIGURE 3-3 Undriven pendulum time series.

FIGURE 3-4 Undriven pendulum phase space: ‘‘point attrac-
tor.’’

41
FIGURE 3-5 Simulated weather system time series.

FIGURE 3-6 Simulated weather system phase space: ‘‘strange
attractor.’’

42
Chaotic Market 43

Take a loo kat Figures 3-5 and 3-6. Figure 3-5 depicts the time
series of a simulated weather system, suggesting behavior that is
completely random and resembles typical graphs of stoc kmarket
prices. Figure 3-6 depicts a phase portrait of the same system, re-
vealing a strange attractor. Again, loo kat Figure 3-6 as a side shot
of the time-series plot in Figure 3-5, condensing that Cartesian fig-
ure into a phase space portrait.
Limit cycle attractors and point cycle attractors do not exhibit
any sensitive dependence on initial conditions: A pendulum without
permanent mechanical force will always end up at the point of origin
(its point attractor) no matter where it started, and a pendulum with
permanent mechanical force will always orbit in its loop (its limit
cycle attractor) no matter where it started.
Systems containing strange attractors do exhibit sensitive depen-
dence on initial conditions: Where the system is at some future mo-
ment will be determined by where the system started (or by where
it was at any time before).

Stretching

Phase portraits depict all possible states of a system by plotting a
variable’s value against the possible values of all other variables. The
dimension of the phase space is equal to the number of variables
that describe the system. Whether a system exhibits sensitive depen-
dence on initial conditions can be determined by numbers called
Lyapunov exponents (LEs), named for the Russian mathematician
Aleksandr Lyapunov, who discovered them.8
LEs measure the speed of a variable’s movements in phase space
versus another variable. Positive LEs measure stretching in phase
space—the speed of divergence of one variable with respect to an-
other variable. Negative LEs measure contracting in phase space—
the speed of system restoration after being perturbed. Thus, LEs for
point attractors and limit cycles never are positive because such sys-
tems are always contracting.
In the case of a point attractor, the dimensions always converge
to a fixed point, the origin; in the case of a limit cycle attractor, all
the dimensions converge into one another except one, whose relative
position creates the loop by not changing (and whose LE is therefore
zero). For a strange attractor—involving a system that does exhibit
sensitive dependence on initial conditions—at least one LE must be
positive such that there is divergence in the nearby orbits.


44 A Tale of Two Markets

LEs were created for use in connection with information theory,
to specify the likelihood that information conveyed in binary com-
puter language would be understood properly. LEs measured the
increase in uncertainty of a communication as additional bits of in-
formation were added to the system.
The notion of bits of information has been reconceptualized for
application to public capital markets as measures of our knowledge
of current conditions. For example, in a time series of stoc kprice
data (e.g., daily returns), a positive LE would indicate the amount
of information or predictive power lost each day.
An LE of .05 per day, for example, would mean that information
becomes useless after 20 days (i.e., 1/.05). Thus, the LE is a measure
of the reliability of information in making forecasts for specified pe-
riods.
Peters, the Boston money manager, also has calculated the LE
for the S&P 500 (1950–1989), using monthly data. His calculations
resulted in a stable LE equal to .0241 per month. An LE of .0241
per month means that information reliability decays at the rate of
.0241 bit of accuracy each month; thus, the average cycle length of
the system using this measure is approximately three and a half years
(1/.0241 approximately 42 months). Note that this result substan-
tially matches the result that Peters got in his H analysis.
Peters also calculated the LE of 90-day trading data for the S&P
500 (1928–1990) and found an LE of .09883 per period. That result
substantially matches both the monthly LE and the H analysis: The
average cycle length of the system was approximately four years
(1/.09883 approximately ten 90-trading-day periods). Based on
these calculations, the public capital markets do exhibit sensitive
dependence on initial conditions and chaotic behavior rather than
simple linear efficiency.

Fractals

Another way to test for chaos is to determine whether a system has
a fractal dimension. Systems with fractal dimensions do not follow
Euclidean laws. Euclidean geometry simplifies and organizes nature
dimensionally: There are points, which lac kdimension; lines, which
have one dimension; planes, which have two dimensions; and solids,
which have three dimensions. These simplifying images are heuris-
tics: Natural objects do not conform to these images. Until fractal


Chaotic Market 45

geometry was developed, however, these integral dimensions were all
we had to go on.
Fractal geometry was developed initially by the mathematician
and scientist Benoit Mandelbrot, who won the 1993 Wolf Prize in
physics.9 He observed that natural objects are not as simple as the
descriptions offered by Euclidean geometry: “Clouds are not spheres
[and] mountains are not cones.” For example, how would we classify
a piece of paper crumpled up an infinite number of times in terms
of Euclidean geometry?
It is not three-dimensional because it is not a pure solid form (it
has creases and crevices). (In mathematical terms, it is not com-
pletely differentiable across its entire surface.) It is also not two-
dimensional because it has depth. In fact, its dimension is between
two and three. That property makes the crumpled paper a fractal:
Its dimension is a fraction (two point something).
With respect to time-series data, dimensionality depends on
whether the system from which the data are taken is random or
nonrandom. If a system is random, time-series data taken from it
will reflect that randomness and have as large a dimension as can
possibly be. In the case of data being presented on a sheet of paper,
the highest possible dimension is two (the dimension of the paper
itself). In any case, the data will fill a plane.
If a system is nonrandom, time series of data taken from it will
reflect that nonrandomness and show a fractal dimension: The data
will not fill the plane but will clump together. That clumping to-
gether reflects the correlations influencing the data (i.e., causing it
to be nonrandom).
These properties distinguishing random from nonrandom time
series may be conceptualized in a different way. For example, our
conception of a crumpled piece of paper as a three-dimensional ob-
ject can be regarded as embedding a fractal in a dimension greater
than itself. That greater dimension is called the embedding dimen-
sion.
Fractals retain their fractal dimension when placed in an em-
bedding dimension; random distributions do not. Thus, unlike non-
random distributions, random distributions fill their space the way
gas fills a volume: The gas spreads out because there is nothing to
bind the molecules together. This is, of course, the defining char-
acteristic of Brownian motion as discussed earlier.
Peters calculated the fractal dimension of the S&P 500 as 2.33
and did the same for other global stoc kmarkets, all of which also


46 A Tale of Two Markets

turned out to be fractals. Japan’s was 3.05; Germany’s, 2.41; and the
United Kingdom’s, 2.94. That is strong proof indeed that stoc kmar-
kets are not best described by EMT.

COMPLEXITY

Thin kabout the 1987 crash (and other roller coaster market epi-
sodes) in terms of Einstein’s point that time operates in different
ways in different contexts. An intuitive case that market crashes ex-
hibit chaotic behavior starts to emerge. The intuitive case begins by
taking a nonlinear perspective of market time, under which market
time expands (speeds up) when trading is heavy and compresses
(slows down) when trading is thin. The speed of market time—called
intrinsic time—evidences itself in pricing persistence and pricing
discontinuity.
Pricing persistence is described in chaos theory as the Joseph
effect, drawn from the familiar biblical story of Joseph interpreting
the pharaoh’s dream to mean seven years of feast followed by seven
years of famine. The presence of this phenomenon in public capital
markets is exhibited by bull markets and bear markets in that iden-
tifiable trends emerge and endure for significant time periods.
Pricing discontinuity is described in chaos theory as the Noah
effect, taken from the biblical story of the Flood. Public capital mar-
kets exhibit the Noah effect in price changes. For example, suppose
IBM opens at 50 and closes at 30. That does not necessarily mean
that during some point in the trading day an investor could have
traded IBM at 40 (or any other price between 50 and 30). Rather,
the price of a stoc kmoves discontinuously in the sense that at one
moment it may be trading at 45 and at the next it cannot be sold
for more than 35 (something that day traders see a lot of and that
is discussed further in the next chapter).
The alternating presence of price persistence (the Joseph effect)
and price discontinuity (the Noah effect) shows that chronological
time—a linear concept—is not the most precise temporal measure
of public capital market phenomena. When discontinuous pricing—
the Noah effect—dominates a market, wide swings occur and mar-
ket pricing is relatively unstable because intrinsic time and trading
activity outpace chronological time and information gathering.
When price persistence—the Joseph effect—dominates a market,
pricing is relatively stable because intrinsic time is approximately
equal to or slower than chronological time.


Chaotic Market 47

The speed of intrinsic time may differ from that of chronological
time. Price changes would then move ahead of information changes.
Investors and other market participants conform perfectly neither to
the linear assumption of homogeneous expectations nor to the ubiq-
uitous irrationality of noise theory.
Instead, investors have heterogeneous expectations that may or
may not be rational and that may be defined according to a number
of variables. Chief among them are investor time horizons that range
from the very short term (for day traders and minute traders and
market makers, say) to the very long term (for central banks, say).
The range of different time dimensions contributes to the Joseph
and Noah effects, persistence, discontinuity, and premature and de-
layed adjustments to information. Short-term traders react more
quickly to new information; long-term investors react more slowly.
Therefore, information changes will not produce proportionate price
changes. Indeed, volatility will increase when there are greater num-
bers of short-term traders (day traders) than long-term traders.
Changes that are produced constitute new information, produc-
ing another round of price changes again defined according to a
range of discrete time dimensions. Adding further complexity to this
mix of investor heterogeneity and time dimensions is the increasingly
global nature of financial markets: News itself is dynamic, traveling
around the world, usually in 24-hour cycles, and impacting Tokyo,
then London/Frankfurt, then New York, and around again.
In this reality, it seems implausible to claim instantaneous, un-
biased market adjustment to new information and it is not necessary
to attribute all market preadjustment or readjustment to irrational
noise trading. Incremental information changes in a perfect market
would be expected to produce proportionate price changes.
But informational changes produce disproportionate changes. In
terms of chaotic dynamics, these disproportionate changes may be
seen as a result of initial measurement error that (as in the hockey
puc kexample and the butterfly effect generally) leads to exponen-
tially greater price changes over time.

BEHAVIORAL FINANCE

Not only do these systemic complexities and the stickiness of prices
show new reasons to be skeptical of EMT, they also suggest partial
explanations for the observed nonlinear dependence of stoc kprices
and the possible presence of chaotic phenomena. They certainly


48 A Tale of Two Markets

show that market behavior is far more complex than EMT allows.
While that is bad news for market efficiency, it is good news for
investors who recognize reality.
EMT may remain valuable to economists in explaining portions
of market processes—the public capital markets alternately may in-
volve both random and nonrandom components. But this partial va-
lidity must not be misunderstood to suggest that markets are “rela-
tively efficient,” “reasonably efficient,” “sufficiently efficient,” or
“more efficient than not” at any moment in time, as many devotees
of EMT have been forced to argue since the market crash of 1987
shoo kconfidence in that theory.
Since 1987, a new generation of economists has arisen in prom-
inent universities to challenge EMT. Led by Robert Shiller of Yale,
a school of thought called behavioral finance draws on a wide range
of disciplines—including economics, psychology, biology, demogra-
phy, sociology, and history—to challenge the essentially mathemat-
ical underpinnings of EMT.
The pioneers of behavioral finance have found substantial evi-
dence supporting two of Buffett’s long-held and most commonsense
propositions. The first is that while stoc kprices over short horizons
bounce around a lot, wedging price and value, over long horizons
the price must correspond to value. As Andrei Shleifer of Harvard
puts it, summarizing the studies: “Stocks with very high valuations
relative to their assets or earnings (growth or glamour stocks), which
tend to be stocks of companies with extremely high earnings growth
over the previous several years, earn relatively low ris kadjusted re-
turns in the future, whereas stocks with low valuations (value stocks)
earn relatively high returns.”10
The second is evidence showing that investing in the latter group
of stocks (mislabeled “value stocks,” but the label is useful to sim-
plify the discussion) offers superior returns over long horizons. How-
ever measured, the evidence Shleifer and his colleagues compiled
shows that “value” stocks outperform “growth” stocks by spreads of
about 8 to 10% annually over long horizons.
As early as 1981, Shiller showed that stoc kmarket prices are too
volatile to accord with EMT. Shiller’s peers at that time skewered
him for this blasphemy, but his research has held up and attracted
a still small but growing following, including former Harvard pro-
fessor Lawrence Summers, who became secretary of the treasury.
Shiller examined the relationship between price changes and sub-
sequent cash paid to stockholders and found remarkable irregularity


Chaotic Market 49

(bouncing around) in price changes in contrast to remarkable
smoothness in the cash stream.
Shiller and his colleague John Campbell recognize that some of
the price changes are due to changes in fundamental information
and to uncertainty about the future trends of cash flows. But taking
account of these factors, Shiller and Campbell estimated that only
27% of the annual return volatility in U.S. stoc kmarkets is justified
in terms of fundamental information. Campbell followed up this re-
search with John Ammer by using more recent data and reduced the
estimate to only 15%.11
Markets may be relatively efficient only on some days but not on
all days or may be relatively efficient for some stocks but not for
others. Even if we are more generous than the 15 to 27% suggested
by these studies and say EMT is 80% correct, it is a grave mistake
to use market efficiency as the basis of a managerial or investor game
plan. Buffett sums it up: “Observing correctly that the market was
frequently efficient,” EMT devotees “went on to conclude incorrectly
that it was always efficient. The difference between these proposi-
tions is night and day.”12 That difference between night and day is
all that Graham and Buffett need to recognize. Neither is enthused
by mathematical accounts of markets, except to agree that EMT does
not explain all of market behavior.
Buffett quotes one of Charlie Munger’s favorite sayings to de-
scribe the modern economist’s penchant for building EMT and re-
lated mathematical models of stoc kmarkets: “To a man with a ham-
mer, every problem looks like a nail.”13 Graham quotes Aristotle: “It
is the mar kof an educated mind to expect that amount of exactness
which the nature of the particular subject admits. It is equally un-
reasonable to accept merely probable conclusions from a mathe-
matician and to demand strict demonstration from an orator.”14
Graham concludes that “the wor kof a financial analyst falls
somewhere in the middle between that of a mathematician and an
orator.”15 The vanguard theorists of behavioral finance stand a better
chance of finding that middle road than do the devotees of EMT,
but they admit they still have a long way to go in understanding
investors and markets, a tas kthat is likely to get harder rather than
easier, as the next chapter explains.


C h a p t e r 4

AMPLIFIED
VOLATILITY

he efficient market story and the chaotic market story are neither
Texhaustive nor mutually exclusive accounts of market behavior.
Rather, they depict end points on a continuum ranging from perfect
pricing to substantial deviation between price and value. These polar
points at the outer ranges of the continuum are a function of the
amount of price volatility. Price volatility can move prices toward
values (and is efficient) but can also push prices away from values
(and is inefficient).
Measuring how much market behavior is captured by the effi-
ciency story or the chaos story is hard. But if a generous estimate is
that EMT has explained about 80% of stoc kmarket behavior in the
past couple of decades, an important question is how much it is
likely to explain in the future. To answer that question, we need to
thin kabout the sources of volatility in pricing and assess whether
those sources are trending toward greater efficiency or greater price-
value discrepancies.
The sources of volatility that lead prices to part from fundamental
values are (1) the quality of information used by market participants in
trading, (2) the complexity of the markets in which trades are effected,
and (3) the discipline of market participants. A good prognosis is that
with the rise of on-line and computer-based trading and the spread of
fountains of noisy information all through the Internet, day and min-
ute traders will drive market mania to an ever more acute state of bi-
polar disorder. Chaos rather than efficiency seems ascendant.

INFORMATION VOLATILITY

The first source of stoc kmarket volatility relates to information
changes. Information volatility has both a positive (efficient) dimen-
sion and a negative (inefficient) dimension.

51

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use



52 A Tale of Two Markets

The efficient dimension of information volatility is simply the
market’s facilitation of price changes in the light of fundamental
information about a company. That information alters the uncer-
tainty associated with that company’s future business prospects.
When the U.S. Supreme Court announces that the U.S. Food and
Drug Administration (FDA) lacks the authority to regulate tobacco
products, for example, the prices of tobacco stocks change to reflect
greater certainty about the regulatory environment.
This type of volatility is inherent in any market. It reflects the
simple reality that stoc kmarket prices are gauges of the future value
of cash flows to shareholders. The ineradicable uncertainty in that
gauge means that prices in an efficient market will hover about the
best estimates of value. But as information changes, the degree of
uncertainty about that value changes and prices should change ac-
cordingly.
There is little reason to believe that positive information volatility
is any worse or better now than it was a decade or longer ago. On
the one hand, there may be greater uncertainty in business value as
a result of globalization, the pervasiveness of new technology, and
the seeming swiftness of its change. A portion of the substantial
price volatility of the late 1990s and early 2000s may be a function
of such greater business volatility. On the other hand, there are also
superior ways to measure business and financial risk, manage it, and
adapt to these changing landscapes. With these factors offsetting
each other, there seems little basis for saying that positive informa-
tion volatility will get better or worse in the future.
Negative information volatility is another story. This inefficient
dimension of information volatility consists of trading on the basis
of information either unrelated to fundamental values or inaccurate
about them. The stuff of negative information volatility includes age-
old accounting trickery (discussed in Chapter 9) and other tactics
designed to prop up stoc kprices, such as share repurchases (dis-
cussed in Chapter 13). But none of these problems seem more (or
less) severe than they ever did. Wacky trading strategies such as
those based on hemline levels and Super Bowl winners also consti-
tute negative information volatility, but these strategies are as fash-
ionable (and foolish) as they ever were.
What’s new is an increase in negative information volatility that
arises from trading that is based on premature information dissem-
ination, unfounded and untrue rumors, false speculative hunches,
and hopes, dreams, and lies. Changes in the manner and speed of


Amplified Volatility 53

information flows produce fountains of high-quality information
along with a deluge of low-quality jun kmasquerading as informa-
tion. The result is increased negative information volatility that
drives a wider wedge between price and value.
In the old economy, EMT seemed plausible in part because the
information that markets digested had a superior quality compared
to that in the new economy trading environment. Old economy news
benefited from the major filtering role played by the mainstream
press. You could count on the integrity of The New York Times, USA
Today, The Wall Street Journal, and other great newspapers and mag-
azines to deliver news and information that was professionally vetted
under constraints imposed by long-nurtured and valuable reputa-
tions for journalistic quality and integrity.
While you still can count on such media for filtered and consid-
ered news reporting, the process of getting there has been littered
with unfiltered information that gets out before its time. The days
of getting vetted news from the morning paper and the evening news
are numbered. Americans get a steady diet of news throughout the
day, with the newspaper and the evening broadcasts sandwiching
nonstop cable news programs, Internet reports, and e-mails for-
warding rumor-based “news” that your friends or colleagues fear you
might otherwise miss.
The deluge of “news by the second” disrupts the old fixture of
the news cycle. Reporters who used to wor kon a 24-hour news cycle
that entailed gathering, researching, writing, rewriting, and printing
the news now announce their results as they go. Print journalists
broadcast tomorrow’s stories on today’s market wraps, and the re-
ports flash around every other news outlet—cable, Internet, and tra-
ditional wires.
By the time this new news cycle is finished, the news that ac-
tually gets reported in print is often either stale or discovered to be
less important than first believed. Reporting quality is sacrificed for
speed. In this world you get data earlier, but you get it the way
journalists in the middle of the old news cycle used to get it: unfil-
tered—the draft of a story in progress.
These forces were behind the $2 billion price plunge of Emu-
lex, manufacturer of fiber optic communications equipment, in Au-
gust 2000. Major news organizations, including Bloomberg, Dow
Jones, and CBS.Marketwatch.com, distributed what turned out to
be a fake press release announcing that Emulex’s CEO had resigned
and that it planned to restate its earnings for the prior two years.

54 A Tale of Two Markets

The hoax was engineered by a former employee of a press service
who knew the ropes of getting releases onto the Internet and re-
ported by organizations eager to be first to get news out. Apart from
the devastation to the stoc kof Emulex, the hoax appeared respon-
sible for dragging down the stoc kprices of numerous other fiber
optic companies as well as the broader Nasdaq composite.1
Webcasting by brokerage firms can also be a source of negative
information volatility. Supplanting the traditional news media, ana-
lysts of major brokerages increasingly post reports directly on their
own Web sites by video streaming. They opine on market conditions
and call attention to favored stocks. Most firms admit they are not
reporting news but claim instead to be giving information. The dif-
ference is often lost on investors consuming the data, who trade on
its basis without recognizing that it is furnished as a marketing de-
vice for the brokerage rather than as news vetted and constrained
by traditional journalistic ethics of independence.
But the real villains of negative information volatility are the
cobwebs of Web sites that pump out unfiltered information on the
Internet with unbridled abandon, particularly on bulletin boards and
chat rooms. The ease and often anonymous character of information
dissemination over these Internet forums eliminates an important
filter for vast channels of what only passes for news and information.
If it has always been hard to believe that the market is as omniscient
as EMT says it is, the increasing ability of anyone, anywhere—iden-
tified or anonymous—to spread lies, rumors, hunches, and other
disinformation to millions at a time makes that concept downright
fantastic.
On a typical day over thirty thousand messages flood the four
largest boards: Yahoo!, Silicon Investor, Motley Fool, and Raging
Bull. None of these board providers screen the messages for accu-
racy, and all leave them up after they are posted. All of them permit
anonymous messages, and all posters can use as many different
names as they want.
For less than it costs to buy a cappuccino, anybody can drop by a
cyber cafe', log on, use one of many services that facilitate anonymous
postings that are nearly impossible to trace (cutely called “anonymiz-
ers”), and say anything he or she wants to about any company (or any-
thing else, for that matter). The SEC has some investigators who reg-
ularly review sites looking for possible fraud and some companies try
to address the rumors they see flying around, but these efforts cannot
assure you that what you are reading is worth anything.


Amplified Volatility 55

The most innocuous form of the ris kof negative information
volatility is the rumor mill—Internet postings that stop way short of
fraud—but these rumors can have equally significant effects on
stoc kprices. Berkshire Hathaway’s stoc kprice was hurt when wholly
unfounded and viscous rumors that Warren Buffett’s health was fail-
ing spread all over the Internet in early 2000. Equally vicious were
the rumors spread in 1996 that executives of Quigley Corporation, a
company that had just introduced a cold remedy called Cold-Eaze,
were really mobsters: Its stoc kprice dropped from $37 to $10 on the
lies. Worst of all was the day when Michael Hackworth, president
and chief executive officer of Cirrus Logic, clicked on a Yahoo! site
to a message pronouncing him “dead after a long illness.”2
More pernicious than rumors in motive and in their effect on
stoc kprice accuracy are the deliberate defrauders, those who have
adapted a host of age-old fraud techniques to the Internet at a very
low cost and a very low ris kof detection.3 Spamming is one of the
Internet defrauders cheapest mechanisms of deceit. For a few hun-
dred dollars, a spammer can buy software that enables the harvest-
ing of thousands of e-mail addresses from Internet files. A whole
e-mailing list can be devised. For higher stakes—say, $10,000—
spammers can buy e-mailing lists numbering tens of millions of ad-
dresses. They blitz them for bogus bucks.
These spammers sometimes get caught. One who did promoted
stocks by spamming to several million e-mailees, touting the stocks
of two companies in exchange for a fee. The spammer did not dis-
close his true identify or the fact that he was being paid to do the
hawking. A California court in October 1998 slammed the spammer
with a fine and an injunction against doing it again.4 In a similar
case, a convicted felon just out of jail and on probation for previous
securities fraud spammed 30 million e-mailees with lies about his
company that were intended to prop up its price precisely so that
he could generate enough money to repay the victims of his earlier
fraud!5 What a Ponzi scheme.
A more elaborate spamming technique seeks to disguise the
source of the e-mail and the identify of its sender, making it loo kas
if the message were misdirected to the recipient and making her feel
she had “overheard” a hot tip being exchanged between friends. In
one case, two men indicted in early 2000 on charges of securities
fraud “made” more than $1 million by sending hundreds of
thousands of e-mail messages about dozens of small companies to
subscribers of America Online (AOL).6 The subject stocks were just


56 A Tale of Two Markets

the kind lots of 2000s maniacs salivate for: no earnings and no rev-
enue, though most of them also had no continuing operations. In a
number of other cases, spammers disguised the sender of e-mails to
make it loo kas if the recipient were reading an internal memo at a
major investment banking house containing “inside” information
about various stocks.7
It has always been true that “tips” are suspect—whether from
your neighbor across the bac kfence, your hairdresser, or your den-
tist. The great investor Phil Carret advised avoiding them like the
plague;8 an astute chronicler of trading markets, Edwin LeFe`vre,
stingingly observed that “Wall Street professionals know that acting
on ‘inside’ tips will brea ka man more quickly than famine, pesti-
lence, crop failures, political readjustments, or what might be called
normal accidents”;9 and Ben Graham was terser: “Much bad advice
is given free.”10
What is different about the new tips is that more people create
them, more people hear them, and more people act on them than
ever before. When adapted for the Internet, not only do classic fraud
schemes dramatically enlarge the number of possible victims (and
the dollar receipts of the perpetrator), when peddled on many fi-
nance bulletin boards and chat rooms they can carry special weight.
This is the case because these boards and rooms often create a spirit
of camaraderie among their users that generates trust in other par-
ticipants and what they have to say.
The most classic scam being adapted to the Internet is the pump-
and-dump, and it has been going on for many years. As early as
October 1996, for example, a pumper bought shares of Omnigene
Diagnostics for around $1 each and then posted a slew of pretty
much identical lies on AOL boards saying that the company was hot
and sales were growing rapidly. The stoc ksprinted to nearly $7 in
about six weeks, whereupon the pumper dumped the stoc kfor an
illicit but huge gain. The lies were dispelled when an employee of
Omnigene announced on the company’s own Web site all sorts of
operational and financial problems. The SEC ordered a halt in trad-
ing of the company’s stock. When it later lifted that halt, the stoc
traded bac kbelow the $1 a share it had been resting at before the
pump-and-dump.11
A more recent pump-and-dump example began one Friday after-
noon in late November 1999, when three Beverly Hills twenty-
somethings bought fifty thousand shares of a bankrupt commercial
printing company, NEI Webworld, for nickels and dimes a share.


Amplified Volatility 57

They then spent the weekend on computers at UCLA bombarding
three popular finance message boards—Yahoo!, Raging Bull, and
Freerealtime—with some five hundred fabricated messages hyping a
pending buyout of the worthless company. The lies jacked up NEI’s
stoc kprice to open at $8 Monday morning and move to a high that
day of $15, while the troika cashed in their shares for a net booty of
about $364,000, plunging the price bac kto the nickels and dimes
they had “invested.”12
The SEC and the U.S. attorney’s office in California jumped on
this scam and in a matter of days identified the looters and charged
them with violating federal securities laws against telling material
lies in connection with the purchase or sale of securities. The SEC
rightly denounced much of the nonsense that is spewed in Internet
bulletin boards and chat rooms as having no more value than graffiti,
and The Wall Street Journal rightly declared that some of them can
be worse than trash.
Of all the known Internet trashers, Yun Soo Oh Par kis the most
notorious. Called Tokyo Joe, he was subjected to civil fraud charges
in early 2000 by the SEC for putting misleading investment infor-
mation on his Internet site. During 1998 and 1999, the SEC said,
Tokyo Joe made hundreds of thousands of fraudulent dollars through
a scalping strategy that involved buying stocks, saying wonderful
things about them on his Web site, and then selling them after the
buying of the masses pushed their price up.13
It may not even be those looking for fast money who sponsor
this negative information volatility. Early in 1999 an employee of
PairGain Technologies put a message on a Yahoo! site directing users
to a fake Bloomberg News page containing a fabricated story that
PairGain was going to be taken over. Its stoc kprice soared on this
“news,” and while the fabricator apparently did not gain any money
from the ploy, he is spending five years on probation for the crime.14
Hard as it is to identify Internet scammers, you cannot count on
the authorities to punish and deter the new defrauders when they
are traced. When the SEC discovered in early 2000 that four third-
year Georgetown University law students (and the mother of one of
them, who happened to be a councilwoman for Colorado Springs!)
had generated nearly $350,000 in illegal profits from a pump-and-
dump scam on their Web site, the SEC “settled” with the scoundrels.
No jail time, no fine, not even disgorgement of the dirty money. The
losers simply had to agree not to do it again.15
In a world where it is just as easy for anyone to buy a share of


58 A Tale of Two Markets

stoc kas to sell it short, the pump-and-dump scheme can be run just
as easily as a bust-and-buy scam. The buster is a short seller who
benefits if a stoc kprice falls because he buys stoc ktoday but prom-
ises to pay for it at a price to be determined later. So he spreads
false rumors that a company’s sales are falling and that it is plagued
with all kinds of problems. The price busts, and the scammer gets
his shares at a low price—and then gets to watch the price rise as
people figure out there was no reason for the bust in the first place.16
That is precisely what the drafter of the fake press release about
Emulex was trying to do.
Outdoing the brazen fraud of the perpetrators of these stories
and the lax enforcement is the galactic stupidity of those who fall
for the schemes. To take just one example, any eighth-grader could
have looked up NEI on the SEC’s Web site or any other reputable
database and found that it had filed for bankruptcy a year earlier
and that it no longer had a listed telephone number for its Dallas
headquarters, let alone any assets or operations. Yet you would be
surprised how many people buy stocks on the basis of such Internet
gibberish and buy them without even knowing anything about their
business climate, let alone management or other basic financial in-
formation.
Speaking of eighth-graders, an astonishing number of people
who should have known better lost over a quarter of a million dollars
to a junior high school kid who apparently too kInternet securities
fraud up as an after-school hobby. The child, 14 years old when he
began his scam, posted hundreds of manufactured messages con-
cerning nine different obscure stocks in chat rooms and bulletin
boards and entered automatic orders to sell the stocks once they
reached hype-inflated price levels. Without admitting or denying
guilt, he agreed with the SEC to refrain from doing it again and to
disgorge his profits (though without paying any additional fine or
other penalty).17
These anecdotal accounts and hundreds more untold indicate a
dramatic increase in negative information volatility. Certainly they
do not evidence an efficient market or one that is getting more ef-
ficient. Rather, they help explain the market manias and greed-gloom
gyrations cataloged in Chapter 1. Their limited detectability and po-
licing, coupled with the public’s evident gullibility, suggest they will
continue to plague the market.
You can be sure not only that there are other crooks and swin-
dlers looking for and sometimes finding fast and fraudulent dollars


Amplified Volatility 59

but that negative information volatility will result. That bad news for
market efficiency is not entirely bad news for you as an investor,
however, so long as you steer clear of the pump-and-dump set and
take advantage of the widening spread between price and value that
results from their dirty work.

TRANSACTION VOLATILITY

The second source of stoc kprice volatility is transaction-related.18
This arises from the way prices are formed by market trading. It is
not possible for any party acting alone to set the price of a stock.
Share pricing in stoc kmarkets arises solely as a result of traders’
orders meeting in the market. How they meet in the market to de-
termine prices is important to know but often overlooked.
Trades on traditional markets such as the New Yor kStoc
Exchange (NYSE) begin with a customer who instructs a broker to
effect a trade, say, to buy 100 shares of Dell at $50. The broker takes
that order to the trading floor, where a crowd of traders are at work.
If there were another broker who had gotten a customer’s order to
sell 100 shares of Dell at $50, the two could just swap shares for
their customers. No price change would result, and so there would
be no transaction volatility. That perfect matching of buy and sell
orders seldom happens on traditional exchanges (or on the Nasdaq,
where the chief difference is only that matching is done more by
computer routing of orders than through the physical presence of
people on the floor).
Instead, buyers and sellers place orders with their brokers at
different times, want to trade different amounts of shares, and want
to buy or sell at different prices. In these more typical cases, the
customers have to wait until someone else arrives looking for a trade
on the same terms or have someone else in the market make the
trade. That someone else is there, and she is called a market maker
(on the NYSE) or specialist (on the Nasdaq) in that stock.
When a broker can’t find another broker looking for a precise
swap with his customer’s order, these middlemen (market makers
and specialists) do the trade so that the broker’s customers don’t
have to wait until a counterpart comes along. The middlemen do
the waiting for them, making markets in stocks by buying and selling
shares when buyers and sellers arrive.
Middlemen make money for providing this service by buying


60 A Tale of Two Markets

stocks at a lower price (called the bid) and selling them at a higher
price (called the ask). The difference between the bid and the as
price is called the bid-as kspread. It is the price buyers and sellers
pay so that they don’t have to wait.
The bid-as kspread also compensates the market maker for the
risks he is exposed to in taking positions in stocks so that others
don’t have to wait. Making a market in stocks exposes her to the ris
of error in her own valuations and the valuations of others. Market
makers can make a market at a price below or above a stock’s fun-
damental value.
If they make a market at a price below value, more buyers should
arrive. But the price goes up when buyers arrive (they pay the as
price). Therefore, a maker will sell more shares at the as kthan it
buys at the bid. It may then have to buy more shares to make a
market, and the price will be pushed up, exposing it to losses if the
bid-as kspread is too small.
Market makers respond to that ris kby widening the bid-as
spread—raising the price at which they will sell to buyers and/or
lowering the price at which they will buy from sellers. Transaction
volatility in stoc kprices arises from such changes in the bid-as
spread. It is undesirable volatility because it is driven not by changes
in fundamental values but by a market maker’s exposure to loss from
value errors amid orders arriving at different times seeking different
things.
Market makers also create transaction volatility when they re-
spond to changes in order flow. If more buy orders than sell orders
are coming in, they raise the bid and as kquotes. They do this be-
cause they must assume that the order imbalance reflects changes
in fundamental values. When they are right about that, their raise
reflects positive information volatility (i.e., price moving closer to
value). But when they are wrong about that, their prices deviate from
value and the change creates transaction volatility.
The rise of electronic computer networks (ECNs) has put reg-
ulatory and economic pressure on the traditional exchanges to re-
duce transaction volatility resulting from market making. ECNs con-
duct trading solely on computer screens rather than through brokers,
traders, and market makers. The swiftness and transparency of this
computerized technique allows trades to be handled as in the first
example above, where two brokers swap their respective customers’
mirror trades, and with far less or no waiting time.
Each customer posts his desired trade on the ECN’s screen, say,


Amplified Volatility 61

one seeking to buy 100 shares of Dell at $50 and one seeking to sell
the same. When the price of an offer to buy matches the price of
an offer to sell (as in this case), the trade occurs automatically. The
middleman disappears, and the price is formed directly by two orders
meeting in the market. ECNs can thus reduce transaction volatility
caused by the bid-as kspread required by market makers.
If particular ECN offer prices do not match, however, they still
get posted on the computer along with the bid and as koffers of
specialists and market makers. When the orders don’t match, there
is an “order imbalance” and the screens cannot do anything about
it. A middleman must step in to buy or sell to eliminate the imbal-
ance and keep the market alive.
Even if it were theoretically possible for ECNs to eliminate trans-
action volatility caused by the bid-as kspread required by middlemen,
that could not happen without effectively shutting down the market.
Thus, any reduction in transaction volatility you see coming from
ECNs is not going to eliminate it. And there is some reason to be-
lieve it won’t even reduce it—depending on how markets shape up.

ECNs shoo kup market trading as they proliferated in the late
1990s and early 2000s. The leading players in this market are Island
and Instinet, both of which do a huge business in this kind of com-
puter trading. Any business they get, however, is business that the
traditional exchanges—and the brokers, traders, and market makers
who participate in them—do not get. At stake for traditional bro-
kerage firms is the franchise value from their roles as specialists and
market makers in stocks. At stake for the proprietors of the ECNs
and the on-line and discount brokers who get more order flow
through their use is a new franchise value the systems can create.
Not surprisingly, then, the explosion of ECNs as alternative trad-
ing places produced an excited debate among the traditional firms
and the newer firms and at the SEC and in Congress. All factions
recite a variation of the same mantra: The goal is to help investors
get the best price available each time they trade.
Traditional firms say the goal of getting customers the best price
would be best accomplished by having a single source of pricing
information,19 and so they call for a centralized order boo kwhere all
orders would be posted and through which all participants could
insure that their customers get the best price. The ECNs and on-
line and discount firms say you will get better pricing if you have
lots of competition between firms, and so they call for permitting a


62 A Tale of Two Markets

fragmented system with lots of different order books. The pressure
on all sides is revealed by merger talks between the NYSE and Nas-
daq on the one hand and between ECN leaders Instinet and Island
on the other.20
Given this environment, elimination of transaction volatility is
unlikely. Not only that, any reduction in it through enhanced use of
electronic computer systems as opposed to market makers is likely
to be offset by another development in market trading: quoting share
prices down to the penny (“decimal pricing”) rather than in frac-
tional increments of 1/8 or 1/16.
In theory, decimal pricing would help produce prices that equal
value. Suppose the value of a share is $50.03. In a decimal pricing
system it is quoted at exactly $50.03, whereas in a fractional pricing
system it is quoted either at $50 or at $50.06 (i.e., 50 1/16).
Decimal pricing also has the effect of narrowing the bid-as
spread for the same reason. But it means the spread is changed more
frequently, itself a cause of transaction volatility. While the move to
decimal pricing may not contribute as much to increasing transac-
tion volatility as the rise of ECNs subtracts, on balance the reduction
from ECNs makes only a modest case for improved market effi-
ciency.
The case is cloudier yet when you add the move toward 24-hour
trading. Market volatility tends to lighten when trading sessions are
interrupted, as occurs on the Thursday following Ash Wednesday,
for example. However, some of the greatest market plummets have
occurred on Mondays, following two days off. Whether continuous
trading will promote or retard efficiency is thus hard to predict,
though one lesson from history suggests the latter. The Evening
Exchange operated in New Yor kin the 1860s as a place to continue
trading stocks and gold after the NYSE’s regular daytime hours. It
lasted only a few years, apparently creating and suffering from a
staggering speculative and volatile bubble that led to its demise.21
Whatever value ECNs add in terms of reduced transaction vol-
atility is offset by what they create in a third kind of volatility. The
rise of ECNs has meant a proliferation of places to trade and get
prices. For investors and traders, this means faster and cheaper ways
to trade stocks, at lower commissions, with swifter trade executions
and more after-hours trading. This promotes the democratization of
capital, which sounds nice. But is it?
As anyone who know anything about Warren Buffett knows, the
best investors see themselves as part owners of a business rather



Amplified Volatility 63

than of a piece of tradable paper or cyberspace. But this mind-set is
hard to maintain when price quotes proliferate and distract attention
to value by both existing owners and new shareholders who buy on
spec.
All this action across a broad spectrum of people and places
means more room for psychological influences. That remains true
whether all these trades arise in thousands of different places or
occur in a single place. The resulting prices bear less resemblance
to business values. The irony is that volatility exists no matter what
system emerges, though with the rise of ECNs a greater danger
lurks: trader volatility.

TRADER VOLATILITY

Trader volatility arises when trades are made for purposes unrelated
to the fundamental values of a business. These trades drive prices
to points related more to the motives of the trader than to the busi-
ness value of the company.
The wide range of trading decisions that cause price moves un-
related to business value includes: trading for identifiable economic
reasons of the trader, such as portfolio “rebalancing”; selling shares
to fund personal needs or desires, such as a child’s education or the
remodeling of a kitchen; and, most notoriously of all, day trading for
purposes of speculation and gambling. Let’s start with that one.
Day trading is usually not based on fundamental values but on
momentum, sector rotation, and other technical tactics of the type
ridiculed earlier. When trades are based on these things, they move
prices. Those moves, having nothing to do with values, widen the
gap between price and value. This exacerbates Mr. Market’s peaks
and valleys and feeds irrational exuberance and irrational despair.
Day trading is thus among the worst developments capital markets
have seen in their history for purposes of maintaining an orderly or
sensible market, much less an efficient one.
Many day traders are probably perfectly rational people; many
are not. Aberrations may get headlines, but some of the day trader
stunts captured by the mainstream press warrant attention. The At-
lanta day trader who gunned down nine people and then himself in
the summer of 1999 after suffering staggering day trading losses is a
glaring example. So too is the fun-loving 44-year-old family man who
too kearly retirement with his wife and their $780,000 nest egg only


64 A Tale of Two Markets

to murder the money day trading and then attempt to murder his
wife (he wound up in a South Carolina prison).22
Hardly tales of high rationality, and the woeful tales of these
hapless folks are not isolated examples or aberrations. A Senate com-
mittee held hearings on day trading in early 2000 accompanied by
a blistering report cataloging its numerous plagues. The report fo-
cused on the industry that supports day trading and emphasized the
need for greater industry ris kdisclosure, licensing, and minimum
financial requirements for traders. But it is also a brief against the
sagacity of the pernicious practice.23
The most compelling conclusions of the report are that 75% of
day traders lose money and that a typical day trader has to generate
gains of $110,000 a year just to brea keven after costs! That figure is
breathtaking, but the idea is not new. Classic studies have shown
that someone who tries to time the market and move in and out of
it quickly to exploit its gyrations has to be right 70% of the time to
profit. Do you know anybody who can perform that well consistently?
Even the best hitters in baseball—say, Rod Carew, George Brett, and
even Ted Williams—bat at most .400 (the equivalent of “being right”
only 40% of the time).
An equally important—if slightly more benign—source of trader
volatility is the practice of “rebalancing.” Ironically, this practice was
promoted mainly by those who use modern portfolio theory and be-
lieve in market efficiency. Rebalancing goes something like this: If
you start with ten stocks each bought for 10% of the total cost of
your portfolio, some will rise in price and some will fall. The re-
balancer says that after a year or another arbitrary interval, loo kat
the new pricing. Suppose five went up and five went down, both in
proportion. Now your portfolio has five stocks constituting 75% of
the holdings and five stocks constituting 25%. The rebalancer says
you should shed some of those in the 75% group to reduce their
role in the overall holdings.
This must ran kamong the dumbest things people could do with
investments, yet it is very prevalent. You end up selling the stocks
that seem to be performing relatively well and keeping those which
come up behind. Why would you do that?
It may be rational, but not because your portfolio is somehow out
of balance. It makes sense to sell the good performers only if you ex-
amine the business fundamentals of the companies and decide that
they no longer meet your requirements for holding them: the price ex-
ceeds the value by large amounts, there are clearly superior opportu-


Amplified Volatility 65

nities for wider price-value gaps, the economic characteristics have
deteriorated, or management has changed hands for the worse.
The famed investor Gerald Loeb gave the opposite advice, which
is not easy to follow in the best of circumstances, much less when
contemporary advisers are telling you something else: “If you want
to sell some of your stocks and not all, invariably go against your
emotional inclinations and sell first the issues with losses, small prof-
its, or none at all. Always get rid of the weakest and keep your best
issues for last.”24
Like Loeb, Peter Lynch regards the prevalent practice of rebal-
ancing as backward, saying it is like gardening by watering the weeds
and pulling the flowers. The beneficiaries of this backward gardening
are not the investors or traders who do the rebalancing but their
advisers—who generate fees from trading—and the U.S. federal and
local treasuries—which get tax payments. Buffett put it best in ask-
ing whether it would have made sense for the Chicago Bulls to trade
Michael Jordan on the grounds that he had become too important
and valuable to the team.25
Apart from the stupidity of trading the best picks, the strategy’s
contribution to trader volatility is significant. When trades are made
to rebalance a portfolio in this way, they are by definition trades un-
related to business value (other than fortuitously). The sale of stoc
that no longer “fits” a portfolio puts price change pressures on that
stock. But that pressure, having nothing to do with actual or even per-
ceived value in that stock, simply widens the price-value gulf.
Finally, plenty of people have turned to the stoc kmarket as a
savings account. It is the place where they repose regular sums to
build wealth for planned projects such as buying a home, paying for
a child’s education, and enjoying retirement. It is also the place
where money is stored and drawn on for unplanned funding needs,
such as paying to remodel a kitchen, buying a sports utility vehicle,
and taking trips to exotic vacation spots.
It is hard to quarrel with those who use the stoc kmarket as a
way to build wealth for planned future needs such as home owner-
ship, education, and retirement. These tend to be long-term goals
that enable long-term investing, and so the stoc kmarket is a rational
place to store some of that wealth.
It is far easier to rebuke the use of the stoc kmarket for more
short-term-oriented expenditures. For one thing, there is extraordi-
nary ris kin stoc kmarket investing, especially over short periods of
time. It is simply not a rational place to put resources that may be


66 A Tale of Two Markets

needed to fund ordinary needs such as home repair and ordinary
desires such as recreation.
As to either form of using the stoc kmarket, however, the net
effect on market efficiency is the same. Trading decisions are based
on needs (or desires) rather than on the fundamental values of the
stoc kbeing sold. That has the effect, again, of separating the re-
sulting prices from the actual values.
As more Americans use the stoc kmarket for these purposes—
as traders rather than as investors—EMT explains less market activ-
ity. And as The New York Times said when day trader mania too
hold, America has gone from a nation of savers, to a nation of in-
vestors, to a nation of traders.26
ECNs and discount on-line brokers facilitate trading, rebalanc-
ing, and savings via stocks. Although this positively reduces the costs
of incremental trading, it has an offsetting negative effect of en-
couraging more trades. In the aggregate market, negative informa-
tion volatility and a wilder Mr. Market ensue.
It is like Reaganomics for brokers, as people end up spending
more in commissions under this lower pricing per trade because they
trade more often. Charles Schwab, to give a representative example
of this industry, reduced its average revenue per trade from $64.27
in 1997 to $45.55 two years later while increasing daily trading vol-
ume from 106,000 to 208,000 and growing.27 Schwab’s revenues
soared; you know who paid.
Day trading funds on the horizon will make all these matters
worse. Marrying low-cost trading, screen-based clearing, and the in-
satiable day trader appetite, a former commissioner of the SEC
launched a company in mid-2000 called Folio(fn) to cater to the
rebalancing and day trading set. It offers a fixed annual fee that is
not only much lower than typical mutual fund fees but also lower
than the average cost per trade Schwab and others charge. It uses
a proprietary trading system to match customer trading orders in
house, going to market twice a day with compiled customer orders
to clear any imbalance. Touted as a way to help investors, this day
trading fund will increase trader volatility.28

PROGNOSIS

The main effect of amplified volatility—from low-quality informa-
tion, market fragmentation, and noise traders—is less efficient pric-


Amplified Volatility 67

ing of stocks. The spread has widened between Mr. Market’s cur-
rency (prices, what you pay) and corporate management’s currency
(value, what you get).
The symptoms of that inefficiency and the consequences of that
amplification consist of all the phenomena cataloged in Chapter 1,
including bifurcation of markets (for example, between the Dow and
the Nasdaq) and roller coaster rides of crashes and breaks. Episodes
such as the crash of 1987 and the brea kof 1989 no longer loo klike
isolated aberrations; rather, these and the spasmodic bursts and
busts of the late 1990s and early 2000s evidence a disease that is
not only epidemic but chronic.
EMT was never a perfect explanation of the stoc kmarket, but
whatever purchase it once held is declining further and rapidly in
today’s market climate. It may have had some appeal in an era when
trading enjoyed the benefits of a major filtering role for the financial
press and investment professionals. While these institutions were
never perfect in those roles, their training, knowledge, and profes-
sionalism (and, for advisers, interest in stable markets for under-
writing and merger advisory businesses) too ksome of the edge off
their human infirmities. It didn’t make EMT right, but it did make
it seem plausible.
The rise of the Web, ECNs, day traders, and the individual in-
vestor have produced unfiltered stoc kmarkets that retard rather than
promote efficiency. SEC Chairman Arthur Levitt testified before
Congress that market fragmentation created by the rise of ECNs
could lead the same stoc kto trade at substantially different prices
in different trading forums. Maybe that would create new and ex-
citing arbitrage opportunities, but the chairman’s insight makes the
case against existing stoc kmarket efficiency airtight.
As the next chapter shows, these trends in market behavior imply
that managers and investors should ignore how the market is be-
having with respect to pricing securities and focus instead on their
own knitting: running businesses with strong economic character-
istics and looking for them, respectively.


C h a p t e r 5

TAKE THE FIFTH

nowing that the average cycle length of public capital markets
Kis approximately four years does not give you any tricks to in-
vesting, for there are none. That, plus knowing that stoc kmarket
efficiency is at most about 80% true and getting less so, corroborates
the endurance of Ben Graham’s intuition: Mr. Market is alive and
still not well. The question is what to do with the 20% or more of
market pricing EMT does not capture, and the answer is to take
advantage of it.
Maybe Mr. Market’s manic depression has been better diagnosed
if still not widely understood. Maybe the detection of nonlinear de-
pendence and the upsetting of EMT are like superior clinical diag-
noses of bipolar disorder in medicine. Maybe increasing recognition
of the disease has reduced the denial and given some hope of treat-
ability. But these are just maybes.
What is certain is that the market is complex. Also certain, given
the alternative accounts of market phenomena, is that trading rule
tests and other pat formulas for investing remain nonsensical gib-
berish, though not because the market is efficient but because it is
plagued by emotional disorder.
It remains to navigate the market’s Scylla of gloom and its Cha-
rybdis of euphoria. It is possible to do so because there are bounds
to the mania. The greater fool theory may be true: Buying stocks for
profitable resale at some future time requires that there be someone
out there who will buy what you want to sell. It may be true that
the entire market operation rests upon confidence that in the long
run the market gets things right without too much static or dislo-
cation over the shorter run that it takes to get there.
Market traits of irrationality and chaos undermine efficiency
claims, but that is as far as they go. They do not undermine con-
fidence in the long-run stability of markets. To the contrary, they
mean that opportunities exist for the wise and the cautious, those
armed with the tools of business analysis that enable one to decide

69

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


70 A Tale of Two Markets

when the time is right to take advantage of Mr. Market’s festering
gloom and when the time is right to steer clear of his maniacal
euphoria.
The debate over how much of market behavior EMT captures is
an endless one. This is the case because its devotees tell us that as
it starts to explain less, opportunities arise for informed people (such
as those who act on the mind-set they develop from reading this
book) to step in and correct things. Thus, EMT gets restored. The
endlessly open empirical question is the degree to which one effect
swamps the other.
On balance, the Internet’s negligible business information qual-
ity and the frolicsome day traders acting on it suggest plenty of in-
centive for real investors to get informed and plenty of room left
over after they do. In other words, if the current trading environment
makes it seem that EMT’s descriptive power is going to loo kmore
like 70% in the coming years, people acting on it may be able to
return its power to about 80% after that. Those most able to partic-
ipate in taking advantage of that process are investors equipped with
a business analysis mind-set.

WHO’S IN CHARGE?

From a manager’s perspective, an important consequence of market
complexity is that directors and officers cannot control a company’s
stoc kprice. Hence, shareholders should not expect or require them
to maximize it. Managers can only be expected and required to man-
age their own business and its fundamental values, not how the
market understands that performance. Investors and traders make
those determinations, not managers.
It would be a mistake, however, to allow this reality to immunize
managers from reproach for poor stoc kprice performance over long
periods of time. What this means is only that managers cannot be
held responsible for fluctuations in the company’s stoc kprice that
result from the passions of the marketplace. It does not mean that
a long-term subpar stoc kprice is not a reflection of actual mana-
gerial ineptitude.
Good managers will enjoy average stoc kprices of the company
above the norm; bad ones will suffer average prices below it. Neither
is responsible for, or can claim credit for, the intermittent ups and
downs. As Ben Graham said, “Good managements produce a good


Take the Fifth 71

average market price, and bad managements produce bad market
prices.”1
Managers also undoubtedly attempt to influence the company’s
stoc kprice all the time in ways ranging from the mundane (casting
unfavorable announcements in the rosiest light subject to antifraud
constraints), to the unlawful (manipulating earnings, a subject con-
sidered in Part II), to something in between (say, extraordinary dis-
tributions to shareholders from the sale of debt or assets).
Those attempts, however, are not motivated primarily by a desire
to produce stoc kprices equivalent to underlying business value. On
the contrary, most managers want the company’s stoc kto trade at
the highest possible prices in the market, without regard to business
value. This is a mistake, as Buffett emphasizes repeatedly, for such
delinkage means that business results during one period will not
necessarily benefit the people who owned the company during that
period.2
While investors rather than managers are in the best position to
evaluate and translate into market prices a company’s performance
as measured by its underlying business value, they cannot guarantee
a perfect translation. Information, transaction, and trader volatility
all interfere with the identity between business value and market
price. Even subject to these distortions, however, it is worth an in-
vestor’s time to understand business values and promote their iden-
tity with market prices. The larger investors have greater incentives
to do this and to reap its rewards, which increase in proportion to
shareholding size.
Together, therefore, these insights justify active, informed, large,
and long-term investors focused on business analysis or, in Buffett’s
characterization of Berkshire Hathaway, “major, stable and interested
shareholders” who are “supportive, analytical and objective.”3 In-
stead of asking whether such investors will make EMT more than
about 70 to 80% correct, however, this perspective confirms the
prospect that such investing can take advantage of what EMT has
papered over for nearly three decades: the systemic separation of
business value from market price.

STICKING TO YOUR KNI ING

The separation of business value from market price calls for invert-
ing the usual thinking about investing. Too often tools and people


72 A Tale of Two Markets

use market prices as a metric in valuing a business. That gets the
process backward. Market price is the last thing an investor should
loo kat in a valuation exercise. All the market price tells you is what
you can buy (or sell) a share of stoc kfor.
The market does not at all tell you whether that is a good or bad
deal. Answering that question requires conducting a valuation based
on the fundamental business and economic characteristics of the is-
suing company. These are the tools considered in the rest of this book.
In using these tools, all investors—institutional and individual—
also should appreciate a few other implications of market complexity
that follow from the question suggested at the beginning of this
chapter: What does a stoc kmarket’s four-year cycle length mean? It
certainly means that the most revolutionary investing ideas of the
last 30 years—EMT, MPT, and CAPM—can be misleading.
These are the lessons to relearn:

• It is not a waste of time to study individual investment opportu-
nities in stocks.
• You are likely to do better by thinking about whether individual
investment opportunities make sense than by randomly selecting
a group of stocks for a portfolio by throwing darts at the stoc
tables (as contests sponsored by publications such as The Wall
Street Journal lead many to believe).
• Nor will you do better by using modern portfolio theory’s strategy
of putting your eggs in lots of different baskets based on what ?
tells you the ris kof each basket is.

It should also be noted that one of the costliest lessons of mod-
ern finance theory was the proliferation of portfolio insurance—a
computerized technique for readjusting a portfolio in declining mar-
kets. The widespread use of portfolio insurance helped precipitate
the stoc kmarket crash of October 1987 as well as the market brea
of October 1989, for the models prescribed selling off blocks of stoc
as their prices fell.
That massive an error—on the scale of the entire market and its
participants—suggests that similar errors occurred throughout the
investing population, including missed opportunities for gain by
small investors. Accordingly, you should ignore modern finance the-
ory and other quasi-sophisticated views of the market and stic kto
investment knitting.


Take the Fifth 73

Strategies

You might as kwhether it is worth your time to do hardheaded anal-
ysis of business or whether you would be better off letting other
people do the wor kand then free riding on their effort. Economists
illustrate this free rider strategy by positing a country that taxes its
citizens in order to build a good military. Everyone agrees that this
is desirable to defend against foreign enemies. A tax dodger free rides
on the public good of a strong military while not contributing to it.
Is it possible for an investor to let others do the investment re-
search (pay the taxes) yet participate as a free rider in the market
anyway? Not quite. First, in the classic free rider example, there are
two classes of people: those who pay their taxes and those who free
ride. In stoc kinvesting, there are three: those who do their home-
work, those who speculate, and those who free ride. The addition of
the speculators makes it possible for those who would otherwise be
content with a free ride to exploit the folly of the speculators by
doing their homework.
You might ask, If those doing the homewor kcan gain so much
from the speculators, why doesn’t everyone shift from speculating to
homework? Good question. People should. But they don’t. Ben Gra-
ham and Warren Buffett—the consummate homewor kdevotees—
repeatedly marvel at the inertia of speculators and can only wonder
why so many people choose lemming-like laziness over active anal-
ysis. Yet the speculator is here to stay, as the trends identified earlier
suggest (and not everyone will read or heed this book). Plus c?a
change, plus c?a la me^me chose.
Even the strategies that come closest to resembling the free rider
gambit require some work. The most common version of a free rider
strategy, which may be best for many people, is long-term investment
in an index fund. An index fund is a mutual fund that buys the same
securities that are in a given index, such as the S&P 500. They have
grown to gigantic proportions of total invested capital.4
People are attracted to such funds for lots of reasons. For one
thing, the S&P 500 and similar indexes consistently outperform the
managers of active portfolio funds. Indexes also change relatively
little, and so index funds have low stoc kturnover and therefore lower
costs and better management of taxable gains.
The chief potential downside of indexing is that it pays no at-
tention to fundamentals, emphasizing past returns rather than eval-
uating future prospects. The trade-off hinges on an investor’s ability


74 A Tale of Two Markets

and inclination to conduct business analysis. While using an index
fund gives a reasonable assurance of obtaining the average market
return with very little effort, the investor should still have some rea-
sonable basis for believing that the basket of stocks that constitutes
the index—whether the S&P 500 or something else—is cheap rel-
ative to the value it contains. Making such a decision requires some
sense of the business analysis discussed in this boo keven if it does
not require precise or detailed application of it.
Monitoring of fundamentals is plain common sense. Buyers of a
market index need to know what value they are getting, just as buyers
of shares do. Both can fluctuate on the upside and the downside.
There is no assurance that the overall stoc kmarket will go up any
more than there is any assurance that attendance at major league
baseball games will go up. Both can and do go down.
Patience while holding is not as valuable as research before buy-
ing, for many bear markets extend for long periods of time. Whether
a market is heading up or down is impossible to predict, even over
long periods, whereas there is at least some possibility of predicting,
over long periods, which way a particular stoc kis likely to go.
Stoc kmutual funds are managed portfolios consisting of selected
stocks from the broader market. An investment committee regularly
buys and sells stocks for the fund. The fund’s shareholders pay the
costs of these trades, plus other fees, making mutual funds more
expensive than index funds. They are also more expensive from a tax
standpoint. Mutual fund portfolio changes often produce capital
gains, and shareholders pay the taxes.
The tax consequence of mutual fund ownership shows an ad-
vantage to holding individual stocks. When you make a mistake in
purchasing a stock—it declines in both price and value to the point
where it no longer meets your requirements for holding it—selling
it at least gives you the modest brea kof a tax deduction for the loss
on the sale.
For individual stocks, regular and periodic investing in dividend
reinvestment plans (DRIPs) using the concept of dollar-cost aver-
aging is a sensible alternative for many people. All this concept
means is that regular purchases of a particular stoc kin set dollar
amounts each month (or another interval) lower the average cost of
those shares compared to the average of the prices when the shares
were bought. It insulates an investor from the effects of Mr. Market’s
euphoria by taking advantage of his episodic gloom.
Suppose you invested $200 per month in Procter & Gamble dur-


Take the Fifth 75

ing three months when its stoc kprice on the purchase dates was
$80, $120, and $100, respectively. The average price during that pe-
riod was $100 (80 120 100 divided by 3), but your average cost
would have been $97 (you would have acquired 2.5 shares at $80,
1.66 shares at $120, and 2 shares at $100, and so you would have
invested $600 and acquired 6.16 shares). This strategy can beat Mr.
Market by substantial margins when used over long periods of time.
Staying the course is prudent only if there is a basis for deciding
that price is less than value. Adopting the mind-set developed in this
boo kis important in making that kind of judgment. Monitoring the
relationship of the DRIP’s price to its value using this mind-set is
prudent. Beware, however, that dollar-cost averaging works to reduce
your average purchase price only if you participate during Mr. Mar-
ket’s gloomy moods. It defeats the goal of defeating Mr. Market to
try to time the market by periodically terminating and later resuming
participation.
For all investors (those in index or mutual funds, DRIPs, or in-
dividual stocks) the key point is to develop a mind-set that attends
to the price-value distinction. You can achieve this without neces-
sarily doing all the detailed computations or extensive research dis-
cussed in this book, but it is imperative to embrace the mind-set
these tools reflect as a way to understand business analysis and in-
telligent investing. There are no free rides any more than there are
free lunches.

Diversification of Stock Investments

Unlike modern finance theory, investment knitting does not pre-
scribe a particular diversification of a stoc kportfolio. It may result
in diversification, but not as a requirement. Ending up with a con-
centrated portfolio is sometimes perfectly fine. As Gerald Loeb
noted, most of the really great fortunes were made by concentra-
tion.5 If you thin kabout Johnson & Johnson or Papa John’s Pizza
and find that the prices at which they can be bought are very low
compared to your reasonable valuation, buying only those two stocks
may be all you need or prudently should do.
You should certainly avoid starting a portfolio on day one with a
dozen diversified stocks. It is almost certain that you will not be able
to find that number of stocks on a single day that are offered at
prices substantially lower than their values. Over long periods of
time, some degree of diversification will probably occur, and it is not


76 A Tale of Two Markets

imprudent to maintain it as long as it does not impair your ability
to concentrate on selecting new candidates or keeping up with what
you already own.
An excessively diversified portfolio gives you a different version
of the free rider problem. Just as a tax dodger benefits from a strong
national defense without contributing to it, a bad stoc kenjoys the
price you paid for it without contributing value to your portfolio.
Free riders are less noticeable in larger settings; it is easier to catch
a tax cheat in Canada than in the United States, for example. Like-
wise, the more stocks you have in your portfolio, the less likely it is
that you will catch and punish (sell) those which are free riding on
your wealth and devouring it.
These principles of limited diversification hold only for well-
chosen common stocks that carry a margin of safety between the
price paid and the reasonable value estimated. For those, Buffett
believes finding between 5 and 10 stocks would be sensible; Graham
says between 10 and 30. Graham and Buffett both emphasize that
investors taking more aggressive stances, as professional money man-
agers do, require the same kind of wide diversification casino houses
adopt: The house needs, in Buffett’s words, “lots of action because
it is favored by probabilities, but will refuse to accept a single, huge
bet.”6

Asset Allocation

Excessive stoc kdiversification (and portfolio rebalancing, as dis-
cussed in the last chapter) should be distinguished from a more
fundamental and important investment principle called asset allo-
cation. This principle recognizes the many types of assets available
to investors, not just common stocks. Alternatives include bonds,
cash, real estate, real estate investment trusts (REITs), and com-
modities. These alternatives often furnish attractive ways to store
and build wealth. Their relative attractiveness is potentially greatest
when stoc kmarkets do not appear to offer prices lower than values,
a prudent time to consider investing in these asset classes. Alter-
natives also include any mix of these asset classes invested in tax-
advantaged vehicles such as individual retirement accounts (IRAs)
and 401(k) plans.
Most investors tend to end up with a diversified mix of these
different asset classes: home ownership, some cash on hand, a re-
tirement vehicle, and a stoc kand bond mix. Those who do not
should try to do so. Diversity across asset classes is important as a


Take the Fifth 77

way to preserve wealth. If 100% of wealth were allocated to stocks
and the stoc kmarket overall dragged for a decade, total wealth would
erode. If a portion of the wealth were stored in bonds and the bond
market performed favorably over that time, much of the wealth
would be preserved.
One problem with investments made through tax-advantaged
plans is a lac kof diversification in the asset classes offered. Many
plan menus are weighted disproportionately toward stoc kfunds.
Many people simply elect an even allocation between the items on the
menu. Many others simply allocate 100% to the stoc kfunds. Either
way, assets are allocated heavily toward stocks. Heavy stoc kweight-
ing may be prudent for very young people and even for older people,
but only so long as other (non-plan) assets are in different classes.
Putting all your eggs in the stoc kmarket basket is imprudent
asset allocation. Once you have allocated your assets across different
classes, the portion you allocate to stocks need not be diversified. In
short, asset diversification is far more important than stoc kportfolio
diversification.
Beyond asset preservation, the ultimate issue in asset alloca-
tion—as in investing in general—is the prior and larger question of
opportunity cost. You want to invest your money in the assets most
likely to produce the greatest return in future periods. The general
principles for evaluating that likelihood are pretty much the same
across asset classes. The form of the asset itself guarantees nothing
about its relative attractiveness, a question that depends on its con-
text. That said, there are plenty of exotic asset classes that most
people are better off staying far clear of, ranging from innocuous-
sounding instruments such as convertible bonds to the more mys-
terious zones of private equity and hedge funds (more on this below).
The business analysis mind set is just as important in assessing
these alternative asset types as it is in investing in common stocks.
While each asset type warrants attention to the peculiar issues as-
sociated with it (the price of silver depends on supply and demand
for the metal, for example), a mind-set trained in thinking as a busi-
ness analyst about common stocks can easily adapt itself for appli-
cation to these other asset classes (that is why this boo kconcentrates
on common stocks).

Income Allocation

Asset allocation is less important than income allocation, but most
people get this backward too. People focus on how much they make


78 A Tale of Two Markets

but less on how they allocate income between investment and con-
sumption. The result is a national savings rate around zero.
But if you save more of what you make, it is easier to meet
investing goals since more assets are at work. Those who save rela-
tively smaller portions of their income are more easily tempted by
speculative impulses that make intelligent investing more difficult.
Everyone with income faces the question of income allocation.
You have to decide how much of your income to allocate to housing
costs, food and clothing, entertainment, transportation, education,
and so on. Some people also have the unfortunate chore of deciding
how to allocate income to pay for past consumption in the form of
cumulated credit card debt, automobile or personal loans, and mort-
gages on real estate.
It should be a no-brainer that the high-interest-expense items in
this category should be paid down to zero before an allocator even
thinks about investing in common stocks. If you are carrying a bal-
ance on your credit card accounts that requires you to pay something
like 10 to 18% interest annually, you are wasting your money. Pay
those debts down to zero and you will automatically earn the rate
you otherwise would be paying—guaranteed (something that is never
possible with stocks). The same holds true even for less expensive
obligations such as automobile loans (with average interest rates of
around 8 to 12%): Paying them down to zero with your extra cash
guarantees you that return. It can even be true for home mortgage
loans in some cases: Paying down 6 to 8% debt locks in that rate in
a way that no common stoc kcan ever guarantee.

Margin Trading

The growth in the number and size of margin accounts for stocks—
especially among day traders—suggests that many people foolishly
neglect these simple truths. From 1996 to 1999, margin debt rose
nearly fivefold at on-line brokerage firms and doubled among NYSE
member firms. During the decade of the 1990s, margin debt as a
percentage of total consumer debt quadrupled from 4% to 16%. Yet
many people do not understand that margin loans are not like other
consumer loans.7
Margin traders borrow from their brokers at rates ranging around
9 to 11% in order to buy stocks with the borrowed money. They thin
they can leverage those loans by using the proceeds to buy stocks
whose price rises plus dividends yield greater returns. In euphoric


Take the Fifth 79

markets those people may win, getting returns higher than the cost
of the money. In gloomy markets they get crushed.
When the balance in your portfolio falls so that your margin
loans are equal to about half or more of that amount, you have to
put cash in to pay down that debt (your broker gives you a “margin
call”). If you don’t have the cash, your broker will sell some of your
shares—with or without your cooperation. Add the interest expense
and the trading costs to a reversal of Mr. Market’s euphoria to count
your losses; then multiply that by the number of overextended mar-
gin traders and you have the acute slope of a downhill market before
you.
The big margin traders might as well be high-rolling in Monaco
on borrowed money. Loo kno further than the poster boy of margin-
ized day trading to see the stupefying ris kof this strategy. The most
vocal proponent of this high-stakes game is Barry Hertz, the impre-
sario of a company called Trac kData Corporation. Its marketing
pitch gleefully enthused that investing was easy (“you don’t have to
be a pro to trade like one”), and Hertz advised his customers to day
trade, using borrowed funds.
Hertz at least too khis own (bad) advice to double speculate. So
on Q day (April 14, 2000, when markets plunged), his own brokers
called him to say they needed over $45 million to shore up his mar-
gin account. To do so, Hertz had to pledge over 50% of his shares
of Trac kData.8 Heed the advice of those like Hertz if you like what
happened to him.

Financial Gambling

You would also do well to remember the tragedy of 28-year-old Nic
Leeson, the so-called rogue trader working for the Singapore branch
of Barings. He funded his trading with millions of dollars of bor-
rowed money, and when the market turned against him, he brought
down Barings, the oldest ban kin England and the one that financed
the Napoleonic wars and the Louisiana Purchase!
Leeson ostensibly was doing arbitrage trading, focusing on dif-
ferences in prices of Ni ei 225 futures contracts listed on the
Osaka Securities Exchange (OSE) in Japan and the Singapore Mon-
etary Exchange (SIMEX). He bought futures on one market and
simultaneously sold them on the other. This was a low-ris kstrategy,
since the two positions offset.
Its success led Leeson to another move, a straddle where he

80 A Tale of Two Markets

simultaneously sold put options and call options on Ni ei 225 fu-
tures. This was a medium-ris kstrategy, very effective in stable mar-
kets but dangerous in volatile ones.
An earthquake that rocked Kobe, Japan, in January 1995 plunged
the Ni ei and terrorized Leeson. As the market roiled, Leeson acted
like a heroin addict and adopted the high-ris kstrategy of buying
more Ni ei futures in the vain hope of propping up the fallen mar-
ket.
When the dust settled, Barings’s exposure on the futures con-
tracts ran to a staggering $1 billion, far in excess of Barings’s total
capital. The ban kfell to its knees. Investigators discovered that Lee-
son’s positions had been covered by Baring’s margin accounts while
he was trading, but after the crash—and after Leeson fled Singapore
for Germany—they were not.
During his trading, Leeson told Barings’s main branch in London
the plausible story that he was hedging his long futures positions
with private contracts and was also making hedged trades on behalf
of a client of the bank. In fact, the client did not exist but was a
fictitious name given to an account that Leeson invented earlier for
his own use.
Leeson allegedly funded that account with proceeds from other
trades and used those funds to maintain the margin account balance.
He apparently used the fictitious client account to convince Barings
in London to provide additional firm capital, which Lesson in turn
used to shore up the margin account. In the end, none of that was
enough.9
The Leeson lesson is admittedly an extreme psychological case
tripped up in a mix of exotic securities, excess margins, and fraud.
But the drama is a memorable warning that margins and exotica can
get you in over your head and that mixing them can get it handed
to you on a platter.

Options

A final warning on exotica takes us bac kto Ben Graham’s opinion
on options. Even before stoc koption awards to managers became
commonplace, Graham disparaged the instruments on more general
grounds.
Options originally were attached to bonds and by the 1920s had
expanded as part of other financial innovations Graham regarded as
abusive. When they reappeared more widely in the 1960s, Graham


Take the Fifth 81

regarded “stoc koption warrants” as they were then called, as “a near
fraud, an existing menace, and a potential disaster.” He believed they
created value out of thin air, had no excuse for existing except to
mislead people, and should be prohibited by law or at least capped
at a minor part of a company’s total capital.
The major negative effects of options are dilution of existing
shareholders’ ownership interest in the company—including existing
earnings per share, sharing in future growth, enjoying dividend pay-
ments, voting for managers, and other major corporate changes such
as mergers and (a bit ironically) new option plans. Graham could
see no purpose in options generally other than to “fabricate imagi-
nary market values.” In short, Graham condemned stoc koptions as
criminal, a monstrous and “wanton creation of huge paper-money.”10
Buffett echoes the point less vociferously by saying that “the
business project in which you would wish to have an option fre-
quently is a project in which you would reject ownership. (I’ll be
happy to accept a lottery ticket as a gift—but I’ll never buy one.)”11
The lesson for investors is clear. Stay away from options and stay as
far away as possible from companies in which options constitute a
significant portion of total capital.

ALCHEMY

Stoc kmarket bubbles occur when aggregate capital invested in eq-
uity securities exceeds the amount of profitable deployment oppor-
tunities so that prices exceed values by terrific multiples. They result
from the hope that the stocks people pic kwill turn out to be the
ones that enjoy the profits. But if, say, $100 billion is allocated to
ventures that can only give returns from profitable investments on
$10 billion, then $90 billion in disappointment is going to come—
90% of the dollars will be left standing without chairs to sit in when
the music stops.
The main difference between the musical chairs of market spec-
ulation and the activity at the typical racetrac kis that horse races
take only about two minutes to separate the gambler from her
money. What horse betting and the stoc kmarket do have in com-
mon, however, is that those who study the horses or businesses and
who bet seldom are more likely to be winners than are those who
bet on every race or stock.12 In the early stages of a boom that may
bubble, if you can find the cinch stoc kat a low price and load up


82 A Tale of Two Markets

on that stock, it is reasonably likely that you will win; if you bet on
everything that comes down the track, it is most certain that you
will lose.
Those who bet on everything coming down the trac kadd hot air
to the bubble. It is a large-scale version of the mania that leads to
around-the-bloc klottery lines during hefty jackpots. What creates
most bubbles is the whiff of great riches from something new that
excites people and leads them to irrational behavior or at least herd-
like behavior.
The wildfire of excitement is spread by unchecked rumors of
champagne and caviar dreams come true—stories of riches, rein-
forced by greed. The frenzy spirals, but ultimately breaks. In reality,
only one person wins the lottery jackpot and the multitudes experi-
ence the most expensive case of “monkey see, monkey do.”
Edwin LeFe`vre put it nicely: “The appeal in all booms is always
frankly to the gambling instinct aroused by cupidity and spurred by
pervasive prosperity. People who loo kfor easy money invariably pay
for the privilege of proving conclusively that it cannot be found on
this sordid earth.”13
Real investors are not the same people who wait in long lottery
ticket lines. They realize that “get rich quick” usually means “get
poor quicker.”
For a bit of de'ja` vu, consider Graham’s observation from the late
1960s: “The speculative public is incorrigible. In financial terms it
cannot count beyond 3. It will buy anything, at any price, if there
seems to be some ‘action’ in progress. It will fall for any company
identified with ‘franchising,’ computers, electronics, science, tech-
nology, or what have you, when the particular fashion is raging.”14
In Yogi Berra “it’s de'ja` vu all over again” style, note this similar
vintage Graham lament: “Bright, energetic people—usually quite
young—have promised to perform miracles with ‘other people’s
money’ since time immemorial. They have usually been able to do
it for a while—or at least to appear to have done it—and they have
inevitably brought losses to their public in the end. . . . [I]t is prob-
ably too much to expect that the urge to speculate will ever disap-
pear, or that the exploitation of that urge can ever be abolished.”15
The urge to speculate endures, with vast numbers of people
seeming to accept the declaration of hyperventilating venture capi-
talists and day traders that the new economy of the late 1990s and
early 2000s means that the old rules of the game no longer apply.
An extraordinary statement of these times was uttered by the chief


Take the Fifth 83

economist of a prominent investment research firm who announced
to The New York Times that “we no longer thin kwe know how to
value companies” (to be kind, that confused confessor shall go un-
named in this book).
Valuation has always been difficult, but how much harder now
can it be than it was before? Cash is the ultimate economic pay-
off. If you can’t get to the point of figuring out how long it takes
to get cash and what risks may reduce the amount or value of it,
then it is not that you don’t know how to value companies any-
more but that the things you are trying to value are not worth try-
ing to value.
Proponents of financial alchemy shrin kfrom the mind-set of
business analysis discussed in this book, presumably deeming its
tools conventional, maybe even boring, dull, and old-fashioned.
When people want to be rich now, they relegate the idea of a nest
egg grown with patient discipline to the dustbin of the older gen-
eration’s history, alien territory to freshly minted paper millionaires
and their envious contemporaries.
Unfortunately, this attitude leads to day gambling on stocks us-
ing credit card debt and a “buy now, pay later” myopia that neglects
the inevitable day of reckoning. It also leads to the popularity of
techniques that enable false positive answers to key questions about
a business when traditional tools give negative answers.
In the biotechnology industry in the early to mid-1990s, for ex-
ample, fewer than 10% of companies generated earnings and few
even generated positive cash flows from their operating businesses.
But those companies needed new investment. Since the traditional
measures of business analysis could not tell a convincing story, they
turned to unorthodox measures. The most striking was a measure of
so-called performance known as “cash-burn.” This was the rate at
which a business was “able” to spend cash on new research projects.
The more burn, the better the management and the more desirable
the investment. Crazy?
It is not much crazier than the similar move made in the Internet
and high-technology industries of the late 1990s and early 2000s.
These financial entrepreneurs jettisoned the traditional metrics of
performance and value based on earnings and cash in favor of new
ways to loo kat these questions. Take market share, for example.
Entrepreneurs say, “Look, we have 60% of the market in selling
flowers (or whatnot) over the Internet, and you should give us credit
for that.” Or, more optimistically yet, “We have 10 million ‘hits’ on


84 A Tale of Two Markets

our Internet site every month. Even though we don’t make money,
that’s 20 million (or so) eyeballs, so we must be good, we must have
value, and you should invest with us.”
People do in droves, following a monkey see, monkey do men-
tality. For most—though not all—of those businesses, the flood of
funds is unjustifiable in a business analysis mind-set. (The next
growth industry is likely to be Internet bankruptcy law firms.)
Every frenzy is accompanied by rational-sounding new rules that
attempt to explain the irrationality. In the last century alone, a “New
Era” bull market culminated in the 1929 crash (fueled by the spread
of wonderful new technologies such as cars, electricity, vacuum
cleaners, washing machines, radio, and talking movies), a “Second
New Era” flamed out in 1962’s “New Panic,” and a “New Perfor-
mance Phenomenon” preceded the implosion of markets and mutual
funds in the late 1960s. The stoc kmarket bubble in Japan in the
1980s was fueled by the widespread belief that Japan had created a
“new” economic model that defied the historical principles of eco-
nomics. Market share was king, and companies were rewarded if
they had it and rewarded more if they got it at the price of having
no or low profits, much as in 1990s–2000s U.S. markets.16
This is not to say that market share is irrelevant. Market share
is a standard and useful indicator of the relative performance of
Coke compared to Pepsi, for example, and something both these
companies pursue aggressively in their competition in the beverage
marketplace. And it is significant that Cisco has 80% of the router
market and 30 to 40% in networ kswitches and that DuPont domi-
nates global markets in nylon and Lycra. That kind of market scale
enables a company to lower the cost of sales and general and ad-
ministrative expenses, which translates into higher profits.
But Coke, Pepsi, Cisco, and DuPont make money in their mar-
kets. A larger share of a profitable market is certainly desirable and
a good indicator of strong business performance. The same can hard-
ly be said for a larger share of an unprofitable one. On the contrary,
the greater your share is, the more money you lose.
Aggressive accumulation of market share can be perfectly dis-
astrous for a business. Loo kat what happened to the airline industry
after deregulation. Intense competition for market share drove nearly
all the profits out of that business. The same thing occurs in the
submarkets where Coke and Pepsi compete, driving profits at bot-
tlers for those brands close to zero in some places.
Nor is this to deny that technological changes from the 1980s to


Take the Fifth 85

the 2000s produced significant shifts in the economy. Rising oil
prices, for example, historically throttled the economy, sponsoring
the recessions of 1973, 1980, and, to a lesser degree, 1990. Yet when
oil prices more than doubled during the late 1990s and early 2000s,
inflation remained quite low and no threat of recession loomed. Part
of the reason was a shift to natural gas and greater use by major oil
consumers (such as airlines) of hedging contracts that reduced their
exposure to such price increases.
But a major part of the reason is econographic shifts from oil-
consuming manufacturing operations to oil-independent service
businesses, including those run on the Internet. Manufacturing op-
erations as a percentage of the economy shran kfrom 22% in 1977
to 17% twenty years later. The share of gross domestic product (GDP)
allocated to oil purchases fell from 8.5% in 1981 to about 3% in the
late 1990s. The Internet is surely part of this shift, as it enables the
conduct of sales and distribution businesses at far lower cost than
traditional means.17
Even so, oil prices above some level will still trigger such mac-
roeconomic problems. Indeed, the plunge in the Dow by nearly 4%
in March 2000 was led by a 30% drop in the stoc kprice of Procter
& Gamble. That company issued a warning that its quarterly earn-
ings were going to be way lower than those in the same quarter of
the prior year and much lower than analysts expected. The company
cited as one cause of that disappointment the rising cost of oil,
which it uses in many of its products.
Another part of the shift is surely the increasing value attached
to intellectual as opposed to physical capital. Businesses producing
and selling software or on-line services can grow more quickly and
at lower cost than can those producing and selling automobiles or
oil. Far less investment in factories, plants, and equipment is re-
quired.
There is no reason to believe, however, that those companies as
a whole can grow any faster than the economy overall is growing. In
the end, the old-fashioned companies (the so-called old economy
companies) are the major customers (and beneficiaries) of the tech
upstarts (the so-called new economy companies), so how much fas-
ter can the latter group grow than the former? Some companies
might, but not forever or just because they have in the past (indeed,
the bigger you get, the harder it is to grow). Even if outsized growth
is possible, it cannot be guaranteed.
Even with these shifts, the new economy does not change the


86 A Tale of Two Markets

basic facts of business life that call for investing based on an un-
derstanding of a company’s business climate; some key ratios must
be in the tool box of all smart investors. Even if some of the new
economy business metrics are used, they should be analyzed criti-
cally. Ignoring losses is foolish, but ignoring signs of endurance is
downright stupid.
If you accept growing market share as an indication of future
value, for example, you also have to recognize that slowdowns in
customer growth are a sign of reduced future value. You must agree
that when revenues per new customer fall while costs per new cus-
tomer climb, you go from uncertain to bad. These facts are char-
acteristic of many Internet companies whose stoc kprices actually
rise on this kind of news. These companies include some of the best
names in the “space,” giving reason to thin kthat the new economy
may just be a wolf in sheep’s clothing. After all, something that
seems too good to be true usually is.
People tal kof the new millennium and the unmatched pace of
technological change, but this impression is mistaken. If you comb
through the annals of economic and investment writing over the
centuries, you will discover repeated periodic references to the rapid
pace of technological change and declarations that nothing like it
has ever been seen (historians dubbed the late 1890s and early 1900s
the Age of Optimism, imbued with technological excitement that
makes centennial turns seem the natural apotheoses of exuberance).
Just pause to consider the printing press, the agricultural and in-
dustrial revolutions, the assembly line, television and radio, and now
computers and the Internet.
Even the sober Ben Graham felt constrained to report on the
sense of his time, writing in the relatively recent period of the early
1970s that: “the rapid and pervasive growth of technology in recent
years is not without major effect on the attitude and the labors of
the security analyst. More so than in the past, the progress or ret-
rogression of the typical company in the coming decade may depend
on its relation to new products and new processes.”18 To repeat what
Graham was fond of saying, plus c?a change, plus c?a la me^me chose.

THE LONG RUN

The attitude that drives any mania is as shortsighted as it is short-
lived. Investors need to loo klong down the road of years rather than


Take the Fifth 87

the path of days when thinking about business and returns. How far
will vary with the person’s age and needs, but a minimum time frame
for anyone serious about investing is four years—and way longer for
most of us.
It is customary to call people with a long-term view “long-term
investors” and to say that such investors adopt a “buy-and-hold”
strategy. Apart from using redundant vocabulary (an investor, by def-
inition, is always dealing in the long term), these characterizations
are imprecise.
One reason to loo kat the long term is to realize that while early
investing is better, no one needs to make an investment every day
or even every year. As Warren Buffett says, using a baseball analogy,
there is no such thing as a called strike in investing—no penalty for
sitting bac kand waiting for your pitch to come in. If a characteri-
zation of this style of view is necessary, it is more apt to call it the
“wait-and-see” approach than the “buy-and-hold” approach.
Either of these approaches, however, is superior to the promis-
cuous practices of speculative traders. It is true, to an extent, that
today’s rookie companies are tomorrow’s classics, but it is false, to
a fault, that day traders and their il kact on this insight. The average
holding period for the top 50 Nasdaq stocks in late 1999 was less
than 30 days, and for Nasdaq stocks as a whole it was about 150
days (compared to about 730 days in the late 1980s).19 That kind of
turnover means the speculators are neither picking stocks carefully
(a wait-and-see approach) nor buying them for the long term (a buy-
and-hold approach).
Keynes famously quipped that in the long run we are all dead.
But he wasn’t talking about stoc kpicking. Keynes made that com-
ment in the context of persuading policy makers to focus on short-
term needs that could be met, he believed, only by governmental
rather than market actions. Indeed, the phrase makes no sense in
the stock-picking context, since it is always better to be rich later
than to be poor sooner and most of us will leave family survivors.
Ben Graham expressly referred to stocks when he said that in
the short run the market is a voting machine, while in the long run
it is a weighing machine. This means that the market is risky in the
short run for its wild pricing gyrations but gets relatively stable and
safer over the long run. But what does it mean to say that the market
will eventually price an asset correctly? Doesn’t it mean that the
market is sometimes correct—that it must, as Alice said in Wonder-
land, “sometimes come to jam today”? Not exactly.


88 A Tale of Two Markets

Milton Friedman’s rejoinder to Keynes was that the long run is
just a series of short runs linked in succession. Thus the long run
is simultaneously with us (it was the long run four years ago) and
ahead of us (four years from now). Market price today reflects the
value of a business as long ago as four years, and the price today is
a guess about business productivity and returns some four years from
now. If your guess is better than the market’s, then while four years
from now the market may be getting today’s value of that business
right, you will be that much ahead.
That is the sense in which the market may get it right in the
long term: Four years from now the market will get correct what
Starbucks is doing today; if you are able to assess that performance
better than today’s market crowd is doing, you will reap outsized
returns. The hard question, of course, is how to make that deter-
mination with high success rates.
Warren Buffett takes Keynes seriously, adopting the “till death
do us part” standard. He invests only in businesses he would be
happy to hold forever. It is a commitment not unlike the one you
make to your spouse. The consequence is the same: be patient and
picky in your search.


P a r t II

SHOW ME
THE MONEY

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


C h a p t e r 6

APPLE TREES AND
EXPERIENCE

f market price is the last thing an investor or manager shoul dlook
Iat in determining the value of a business or an ownership interest
in it, the first thing to consider is its fundamental economic char-
acteristics. There are so many approaches to appraising those fun-
damentals that many people use the relatively lazy metric of market
price as a guideline in valuation, but that is a mistake. Of all the
approaches to appraising business value, just a few do virtually all
the har dwork, an dthose are the ones you need. A parable will
illustrate the basics, an dthe rest of this part will fill in the details.1

FOOLS AND WISDOM

Once there was a wise ol dman who owne dan apple tree. It was a
fine tree, an dwith little care it produce da crop of apples each year
which he sol dfor $100. The man wante dto retire to a new climate,
an dhe decide dto sell the tree. He enjoye dteaching a goo dlesson,
an dhe place dan advertisement in the business opportunities section
of The Wall Street Journal in which he sai dhe wante dto sell the
tree for “the best offer.”

Some Red Herrings

The first person to respon dto the a doffere dto pay $50, which, he
said, was what he coul dget for selling the apple tree for firewoo
after he cut it down. “You don’t know what you are talking about,”
the ol dman chastised. “You are offering to pay only the salvage value
of this tree. That might be a goo dprice for a pine tree or even this
tree if it ha dstoppe dbearing fruit or if the price of apple woo dha
gotten so high that the tree was more valuable as a source of woo

91

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


92 Show Me the Money

than as a source of fruit. But you are obviously not competent to
understan dthese things, so you can’t see that my tree is worth far
more than 50 bucks.”
The next person who visite dthe ol dman offere dto pay $100 for
the tree. “For that,” she opined, “is what I woul dbe able to get for
selling this year’s crop of fruit, which is about to mature.” “You are
not as out of your depth as the first one,” responde dthe ol dman.
“At least you see that this tree has more value as a producer of apples
than it woul das a source of firewood. But $100 is not the right price.
You are not considering the value of next year’s crop of apples or
that of the years after. Please take your $100 an dgo elsewhere.”
The thir dperson to come along was a young man who ha djust
droppe dout of business school. “I am going to sell apples on the
Internet,” he said. “I figure that the tree shoul dlive for at least
another 15 years. If I sell the apples for $100 a year, that will total
$1,500. I offer you $1,500 for your tree.” “Oh, no, dot-commer,” la-
mente dthe man, “you’re even more ill informe dabout reality than
the others I’ve spoken with.”
“Surely the $100 you woul dearn by selling the apples from the
tree 15 years from now cannot be worth $100 to you today. In fact,
if you place d$41.73 today in a bank account paying 6% interest,
compounde dannually, that small sum woul dgrow to $100 at the en
of 15 years. So the present value of $100 worth of apples 15 years
from now, assuming an interest rate of 6%, is only $41.73 not $100.
Pray,” advise dthe beneficent ol dman, “take your $1,500 an dinvest
it safely in high-grade corporate bonds an dgo back to business
school an dlearn something about finance.”
Before long there came a wealthy physician who said, “I don’t
know much about apple trees, but I know what I like. I’ll pay the
market price for it. The last fellow was willing to pay you $1,500 for
the tree, an dso it must be worth that.”
“Doctor,” advise dthe ol dman, “you shoul dget yourself a knowl-
edgeable investment adviser. If there were truly a market in which
apple trees were trade dwith some regularity, the prices at which
they were sol dmight tell you something about their value. But not
only is there no such market, even if there were, taking its price as
the value is just mimicking the stupidity of that last knucklehea dor
the others before him. Please take your money an dbuy a vacation
home.”
The next would-be buyer was an accounting student. When the
ol dman asked, “What price are you willing to give me?” the student


Apple Trees and Experience 93

first demande dto see the ol dman’s books. The ol dman ha dkept
careful records an dgladly brought them out.
After examining them, the accounting student said, “Your books
show that you pai d$75 for this tree ten years ago. Furthermore, you
have made no deductions for depreciation. I do not know if that
conforms with generally accepte daccounting principles, but assum-
ing that it does, the book value of your tree is $75. I will pay that.”
“Ah, you students know so much an dyet so little,” chide dthe
ol dman. “It is true that the book value of my tree is $75, but any
fool can see that it is worth far more than that. You ha dbest go back
to school an dsee if you can fin da book that shows you how to use
your numbers to better effect.”

A Dialogue on Earnings

The final prospect to visit the ol dman was a young stockbroker who
ha drecently graduate dfrom business school. Eager to test her new
skills, she too aske dto examine the books. After several hours she
came back to the ol dman an dsai dshe was prepare dto make an
offer that value dthe tree on the basis of the capitalization of its
earnings. For the first time the ol dman’s interest was piqued, an
he aske dher to go on.
The young woman explaine dthat while the apples were sol dfor
$100 last year, that figure di dnot represent the profits realize dfrom
the tree. There were expenses attendant to the tree, such as the cost
of fertilizer, pruning, tools, picking apples, an dcarting them to town
an dselling them.
Somebody ha dto do those things, an da portion of the salaries
pai dto those persons ought to be charge dagainst the revenues from
the tree. Moreover, the purchase price, or cost, of the tree was an
expense. A portion of the cost is taken into account each year of the
tree’s useful life. Finally, there were taxes. She conclude dthat the
profit from the tree was $50 last year.
“Wow!” The ol dman blushed. “I thought I made $100 off that
tree.”
“That’s because you faile dto match expenses with revenues, in
accordance with generally accepte daccounting principles,” she ex-
plained. “You don’t actually have to write a check to be charge dwith
what accountants consider to be your expenses. For example, you
bought a station wagon some time ago an duse dit part of the time
to cart apples to market. The wagon will last a while, an deach year


94 Show Me the Money

some of the original cost has to be matche dagainst revenues. A
portion of the amount has to be sprea dout over the next several
years even though you expende dit all at one time. Accountants call
that depreciation. I’ll bet you never figure dthat in your calculation
of profits.”
“I’ll bet you’re right,” he replied. “Tell me more.”
“I also went back into the books for a few years an dsaw that in
some years the tree produce dfewer apples than it di din other years,
the prices varied, an dthe costs were not exactly the same each year.
Taking an average of only the last three years, I came up with a
figure of $45 as a fair sample of the tree’s earnings. But that is only
half of what we have to do to figure the value.”
“What’s the other half?” he asked.
“The tricky part,” she tol dhim. “We now have to figure the value
to me of owning a tree that will produce average annual earnings of
$45 a year. If I believe dthat the tree was a ‘one-year wonder,’ I woul
say 100% of its value—as a going business—was represente dby one
year’s earnings.”
“But if we agree that the tree is more like a corporation in that
it will continue to produce earnings year after year, the key is to
figure out an appropriate rate of return. In other words, I will be
investing my capital in the tree, an dI nee dto compute the value to
me of an investment that will produce $45 a year in income. We can
call that amount the capitalize dvalue of the tree.”
“Do you have something in mind?” he asked.
“I’m getting there. If this tree produce dentirely steady an dpre-
dictable earnings each year, it woul dbe like a U.S. Treasury bond.
But its earnings are not guaranteed, so we have to take into account
risks an duncertainty. If the risk of its ruin was high, I woul dinsist
that a single year’s earnings represent a higher percentage of the
value of the tree. After all, apples coul dbecome a glut on the market
one day an dyou woul dhave to cut the price, thus increasing the
costs of selling them.”
“Or,” she continued, “some doctor coul iscover a link between
eating an apple a day an dheart disease. A drought coul dcut the
yiel dof the tree. Or the tree coul dbecome disease dan ie. These
are all risks. An dwe don’t even know whether the costs we are sure
to incur will be worth incurring.”
“You are a gloomy one,” reflecte dthe ol dman. “There coul dalso
be a shortage of apples on the market, an dthe price of apples coul
rise. If you think about it, it is even possible that I have been selling


Apple Trees and Experience 95

the apples at prices below what people woul dbe willing to pay an
that you coul draise the price without reducing your sales. Also,
there are treatments, you know, that coul dbe applie dto increase
the yiel dof the tree. This tree coul dhelp spawn a whole orchard.
Any of these woul dincrease earnings.”
“The earnings also coul dbe increase dby lowering costs of the
sort you mentioned,” the ol dman continued. “Costs can be reduce
by speeding the time from fruition to sale, managing extensions of
credit better, an dminimizing losses from ba dapples. Cutting costs
boosts the relationship between overall sales an dnet earnings or, as
the financial types say, the tree’s profit margin. An dthat in turn
woul dboost the return on your investment.”
“I am aware of all that,” she assure dhim. “The fact is, we are
talking about risk. An dinvestment analysis is a col dbusiness. We
don’t know with certainty what’s going to happen. You want your
money now, an dI’m suppose dto live with the risk.
“That’s fine with me, but then I have to look through a cloudy
crystal ball, an dnot with 20/20 hindsight. An dmy resources are
limited. I have to choose between your tree an dthe strawberry patch
down the road. I cannot buy both, an dthe purchase of your tree
will deprive me of alternative investments. That means I have to
compare the opportunities an dthe risks.
“To determine a proper rate of return,” she continued, “I looke
at investment opportunities comparable to the apple tree, particu-
larly in the agribusiness industry, where these factors have been
taken into account. I then adjuste dmy findings base don how the
things we discusse dworke dout with your tree. Base don those judg-
ments, I figure that 20% is an appropriate rate of return for the tree.
“In other words,” she concluded, “assuming that the average
earnings from the tree over the last three years (which seems to be
a representative period) are indicative of the return I will receive, I
am prepare dto pay a price for the tree that will give me a 20% return
on my investment. I am not willing to accept any lower rate of return
because I don’t have to; I can always buy the strawberry patch in-
stead. Now, to figure the price, we simply divide $45 of earnings per
year by the 20% return I am insisting on.”
“Long division was never my strong suit. Is there a simpler way
of doing the figuring?” he aske dhopefully.
“There is,” she assure dhim. “We can use an approach we Wall
Street types prefer, calle dthe price-earnings (or P/E) ratio. To com-
pute the ratio, just divide 100 by the rate of return we are seeking.


96 Show Me the Money

If I were willing to settle for an 8% return, that woul dbe 100 divide
by 8, which equals 12.5. So we’ duse a P/E ratio of 12.5 to 1. But
since I want to earn 20% on my investment, I divide d100 by 20 an
came up with a P/E ratio of 5:1. In other words, I am willing to pay
five times the tree’s estimate dannual earnings. Multiplying $45 by
5, I get a value of $225. That’s my offer.”
The ol dman sat back an dsai dhe greatly appreciate dthe lesson.
He woul dhave to think about her offer, an dhe aske dif she coul
come by the next day.

A Dialogue on Cash

When the young woman returned, she foun dthe ol dman emerging
from behin da sea of work sheets, small print columns of numbers,
an da calculator. “Delighte dto see you,” he said, enthralled. “I think
we can do business.
“It’s easy to see how you Wall Street smarties make so much
money, buying people’s property for less than its true value. I think
I can get you to agree that my tree is worth more than you figured.”
“I’m open-minded,” she assure dhim.
“The $45 number you came up with yesterday was something
you calle dprofits, or earnings that I earne din the past. I’m not so
sure it tells you anything that important.”
“Of course it does,” she protested. “Profits measure efficiency
an deconomic utility.”
“Fair enough,” he mused, “but it sure doesn’t tell you how much
money you’re getting. I looke din my safe yesterday after you left
an dsaw some stock certificates I own that never pai da dividen dto
me. An dI kept getting reports each year telling me how great the
earnings were. Now I know that the earnings increase dthe value of
my stocks, but without any dividends I couldn’t spen dthem. It’s just
the opposite with the tree.
“You figure dthe earnings were lower because of some amounts
I’ll never have to spend, like depreciation on my station wagon,” the
ol dman went on. “It seems to me these earnings are an idea worke
up by the accountants.”
Intrigued, she asked, “What is important, then?”
“Cash,” he answered. “I’m talking about dollars you can spend,
save, or give to your children. This tree will go on for years yielding
revenues after costs. An dit is the future, not the past, we nee dto
reckon with.”


Apple Trees and Experience 97

“Don’t forget the risks,” she reminde dhim. “An dthe uncertain-
ties.”
“Quite right,” he observed. “If we can agree on the possible range
of future revenues an dcosts an dthat earnings average daroun d$45
the last few years, we can make some fair estimates of cash flow
over the coming five years: How about that there is a 25% chance
that cash flow will be $40, a 50% chance it will be $50, an da 25%
chance it will be $60?
“That makes $50 our best guess if you average it out,” the ol
man figured. “Then let’s just say that for ten years after that the
average will be $40. An dthat’s it. The tree doctor tells me it can’t
produce any longer than that.
“Now all we have to do,” he finishe dup, “is figure out what you
pay today to get $50 a year from now, two years from now, an dso
on for the first five years until we figure what you woul dpay to get
$40 a year for each of the ten years after that. Then, throw in the
20 bucks we can get for firewood.
“Simple,” she confessed. “You want to discount to the present
value of future receipts including salvage value. Of course you nee
to determine the rate at which you discount.”
“Precisely,” he concurred. “That’s what my charts an dthe cal-
culator are for.” She no e das he showe dher discount tables that
reveale dwhat a dollar receive dat a later time is worth today under
different assumptions about the discount rate. It showed, for ex-
ample, that at an 8% discount rate, a dollar delivere da year from
now is worth $.93 today, simply because $.93 today, investe dat 8%,
will produce $1 a year from now.
“You coul dput your money in a savings account that is insure
an dreceive 5% interest. But you coul dalso buy U.S. Treasury ob-
ligations with it an dearn, say, 8% interest, depending on prevailing
interest rates. That looks like the risk-free rate of interest to me.
Anywhere else you put your money deprives you of the opportunity
to earn 8% risk-free. Discounting by 8% will only compensate you
for the time value of the money you invest in the tree rather than
in Treasuries. But the cash flow from the apple tree is not riskless,
sa dto say, so we nee dto use a higher discount rate to compensate
you for the risk in your investment.
“Let’s agree to discount the receipt of $50 a year from now by
15%, an dso on with the other deferre dreceipts. That is about the
rate that is applie dto investments with this magnitude of risk. You
can check that out with my neighbor, who just sol dhis strawberry


98 Show Me the Money

patch yesterday. According to my figures, the present value of the
expecte dyearly profit is $268.05, an dtoday’s value of the firewoo
is $2.44, for a gran dtotal of $270.49. I’ll take $270 even. You can
see how much I’m allowing for risk because if I discounte dthe
stream at 8%, it woul dcome to $388.60.”
After a few minutes of reflection, the young woman sai dto the
ol dman, “It was a bit foxy of you yesterday to let me appear to be
teaching you something. Where di dyou learn so much about finance
as an apple grower?”
The ol dman smiled. “Wisdom comes from experience in many
fields.”
“I enjoye dthis little exercise, but let me tell you something that
some financial whiz kids tol dme,” she replied. “Whether we figure
value on the basis of the discounte dcash flow metho dyou like or
the capitalization of earnings I proposed, so long as we apply both
methods perfectly, we shoul dcome out at exactly the same point.”
“Of course!” the ol dman exclaimed. “The wunderkinds are
catching on. The clever ones are not simply looking at ol dearnings
but copying managers by projecting cash flows into the future. The
question is which metho dis more likely to be misused.
“I prefer my metho dof using cash rather than earnings because
I don’t have to monkey aroun dwith costs like depreciation of my
station wagon an dother long-term assets. You have to make these
arbitrary assumptions about the useful life of the thing an dhow fast
you’re going to depreciate it. That’s where I think you went wrong
in your figuring.”
“Nice try, you crafty ol evil,” she rejoined. “You know there is
plenty of room for mistakes in your calculations too. It’s easy to
discount cash flows when they are nice an dsteady, but that doesn’t
help you when you’ve got some lumpy expenses that do not recur.
For example, several years from now that tree will nee dserious prun-
ing an dspraying that don’t show up in your flow. The labor an
chemicals for that once-only occasion throw off the evenness of your
calculations.”
“But I’ll tell you what,” she bellie dup. “I’ll offer you $250. My
col danalysis tells me I’m overpaying, but I really like that tree. I
think the delight of sitting in its glorious shade must be worth some-
thing.”
“It’s a deal,” agree dthe ol dman. “I never sai dI was looking for
the highest offer but only the best offer.”


Apple Trees and Experience 99

Lessons

The parable of the ol dman an dthe tree introduce da number of
alternative methods of valuing productive property, whether a single
asset or an entire business enterprise. The original $50 bi dwas base
on the tree’s salvage value, also sometimes calle dits scrap value.
This valuation metho dwill virtually always be inappropriate for val-
uing a productive asset, business, or share of stock (though many
bust-up takeover artists of the 1980s popularize dthe opposite claim).
The $100 bi dwas base donly on one year’s earnings an dignores
the earning power over future time. The Internet apple maven’s
$1,500 overvaluation ignore dthe concept of the time value of money
by simply a ing together the raw dollar amounts of expecte dearn-
ings over future years. Neither of these approaches even qualifies as
an appropriate valuation method.
The doctor’s bi rew on a market-base dvaluation technique
that considers what other willing buyers ha doffered. But that tech-
nique will be helpful only if the property under consideration or
similar properties are regularly trade din reasonably well develope
markets. Even then, it is circular because it uses the question
(What’s it worth, according to others?) to get the answer (What it’s
worth, according to others).
The deal was ultimately seale dwhen the buyer an dthe ol dman
agree dthat the two methods they used—capitalizing earnings an
discounting cash flows—made the most sense (noting that these two
techniques, if perfectly applied, give the same answer). The buyer
preferre dto use earnings because accounting rules regarding earn-
ings are intende dto reflect economic reality pretty well. The ol dman
ha dless confidence in those rules principally because they call for
deducting from revenues accounting depreciation, which he was not
sure accurately reflecte deconomic reality.
Although reasonable people can differ, both methods show that
valuation is not a fool’s game. The buyer an dthe ol dman both wisely
an drightly acknowledge dthe importance of keen judgment in busi-
ness analysis. As the type of investment you consider becomes more
uncertain, your judgment must become proportionately more razor-
sharp.
Picking an index fun dor even a mutual fun drequires the least
amount of knowledge or judgment; picking a classic stock a bit more,
a vintage stock much more, an da rookie stock the greatest. In terms
of apples, the apple tree the ol dman just sol dis much like a classic


100 Show Me the Money

business, a GE, say, or DuPont or Unite dTechnologies. It is mature
an dproductive an dhas an extensive track record.
At the other extreme might be a dot-com start-up business whose
only recor dis on paper—a business plan that is the apple tree equiv-
alent of a bag of seeds. Even if the ingredients are there, the exe-
cution is entirely in front of you. You may still have a basis for gaug-
ing the probable future—the quality of the seeds, soil, fertilizer, an
farmer—but you are leaving more to judgment than in the case of
the mature tree.
A few a itional morals of the parable: Methods are useful as
tools, but goo djudgment comes not from methods alone but from
experience. An dexperience comes from ba djudgment. Listen
closely to the experts an dhear the things they don’t tell you. Be-
hin dall the sweet sounds of their confident notes there is a great
deal of discordant uncertainty. One wrong assumption can carry
you pretty far from the truth. Finally, you are never too young to
learn.

HORSE SENSE

The ol dman an dhis ultimate buyer share da business analysis mind-
set. That mind-set focuses on individual businesses but must be
forme dagainst the backdrop of a few general conditions—what
economists call macroeconomic conditions: interest rates, taxes, in-
flation, an dthe time value of money (or compounding).

Compounding

A powerful an dintuitive introduction to the time value of money is
given by this characteristically witty vignette by a 32-year-ol dWarren
Buffett:

I have it from unreliable sources that the cost of the voyage
Isabella originally underwrote for Columbus was approximately
$30,000. This has been considere dat least a moderately suc-
cessful utilization of venture capital. Without attempting to eval-
uate the psychic income derive dfrom finding a new hemisphere,
it must be pointe dout that . . . the whole deal was not exactly
another IBM. Figure dvery roughly, the $30,000 investe dat 4%
compounde dannually woul dhave amounte dto something like
$2,000,000,000,000. . . .


Apple Trees and Experience 101

That is $2 trillion—base don a quite modest 4% rate of return.
Not only nothing to sneeze at but something to be joyous over. Buf-
fett calle dthis vignette “The Joys of Compounding.”
It explains the apocryphal story of Buffett riding up a crowde
office building elevator. All heads were staring up at the floor num-
bers lighting across the top, while Buffett was scouring the elevator
floor. As he walke dout, Buffett stoope own an dpicke dup a penny
lying on the floor. The doors close dbehin dhim, smirks crosse dsome
passengers’ faces, an done rider remarked, “That is the start of the
next billion.”
If you think a penny today does not amount to a hill of beans,
consider how much it will grow to over time! That is the joy of future
values of money—they get higher the more compounding there is.
You get compounding in two ways. You can put money away earlier
rather than later, an dyou can get returns (interest or dividends) pai
more frequently an dreinvest them too. That is why building wealth
calls for saving early an doften, though investing only when the price
is right.
Investors grasp the joys of compounding, for it is a useful tool
to evaluate competing opportunities quickly. A handy reference for
making the comparisons gauges how long it takes a given amount of
money to double at varying compounde drates of return (or interest
rates).
Calle dthe rule of 72s, it says that dividing 72 by the rate of
return gives the approximate number of years it takes for an amount
of money to double. For example, an investment yielding a com-
pounde drate of return of 9% will double in about eight years (72
divide dby 9 equals 8) an done yielding 6% will double in about 12
years (72 divide dby 6 equals 12).
The rule of 72s can show all sorts of variations on the relation-
ship between money in han dnow an dmoney to be gotten in the
future. For example, it can determine what require drate of return
is necessary for a certain sum to grow to a desire dsum in the future.
Or if you know what rate of return is available or possible, it can
figure how much money someone needs today in order for it to grow
to a desire dlevel at some future time.
Take an example. If the available average rate of return on money
from now until 40 years from now is 9%, how much money does a
25-year-ol dperson nee dtoday in order to retire as a millionaire at
age 65 without saving another cent over that time? Work backwar
from ending up with $1,000,000 at age 65. Since money earning a


102 Show Me the Money

compoun drate of return of 9% doubles approximately every 8 years,
at age 57 she’ dnee dto have $500,000; at age 49 she’ dnee dto have
$250,000; at age 41 she’ dnee dto have $125,000; at age 33 she’
nee dto have $62,500; an dtoday, at age 25, she’ dnee dto have (only)
$31,250!
If this illustrates the joy in compounding, take another use of
the rule of 72s to illustrate the joy of slightly higher rates of return.
Assume that instea dof being able to earn about a 9% rate of return
over the next 40 years, our 25-year-ol dcan only reasonably expect a
6% rate of return. Now her money will double approximately only
every 12 years rather than every 8. So 12 years hence at age 37 she’
have $62,500; at age 49 she’ dhave $125,000; at age 61 she’ dhave
$250,000; at age 73 she’ dhave $500,000; an dshe’ dhave to reach
the ripe age of 85 to en dup with a million!

Interest Rates

A subtle but most important lesson of the apple tree parable is the
pivotal role interest rates play in the value of assets. The ol dman
mentione dthat U.S. Treasury instruments provide a risk-free rate of
interest. That benchmark interest rate is a major determinant of the
value of any other asset in the economy, including the value of whole
businesses an dshares of stock in them. The risk-free rate sets the
standar dof value of assets with risk. The higher the risk-free rate,
the lower the values of riskier assets; the lower the risk-free rate, the
higher the values of riskier assets.
As Warren Buffett reflecte din a rare public commentary pre-
pare dfor Fortune by Carol Loomis, when the risk-free rate was very
high in the late 1960s an d1970s, for example, the average price of
stocks was depressed.2 The Dow hardly move dan inch in price from
the early 1960s to the late 1970s because for investors to buy stocks,
they ha dto get a return that exceede dthe sky-high risk-free interest
rate. When the risk-free rate was very low from the mid-1980s to the
early 2000s, in contrast, average stock prices shot up. The Dow en-
joye dthe greatest bull market in history because the risk-free rate
was so low that it was relatively easy for investors to get a risk pre-
mium (returns above the risk-free rate).

Taxes

The only thing more mind-boggling about amateur day trading than
the outright losses that are racke dup is how many among the trading


Apple Trees and Experience 103

winners neglect how much they are losing to tax payments both
outright an din terms of the time value lost by the payments.
Suppose you buy an investment that pays 15% per year for 30
years an dkeep that investment compounding yearly until the en dof
that time without being obligate dto pay taxes on it. Suppose also
that you are taxe don your income from that investment at the en
of that thirtieth year at a rate of 35%. This means your after-tax
annual rate of return on that investment was about 13.3%. Har dto
beat.
Suppose instea dthat your 15% per year investment for 30 years
pays you that 15% annually an dsubjects you to tax of 35% each year
you get it. Your annual after-tax return su enly shrinks to about
9.75%. Not a ba dnet return, you say, but that is over 3.5% less than
the tax-deferre dposition. An dnow we are talking about huge sums,
with that 3.5% difference compounding over periods such as 30
years.
The same is true at every level of return differentials an dremains
quite substantial even at lower rates of return. A 10% pretax return
with taxes due only at the en dof 30 years gives you an after-tax
return of about 8.3%, compare dwith about a 6.5% after-tax return
if you ha dpai dtaxes on that income each year. Again, that kin dof
2% difference compounde dover a few decades works out to be lots
of dollars.3

Inflation

Our parable’s business school dropout di dnot know that the value
of money across time is nonlinear. Inflation often differs from re-
turns, an dreturns differ from each other. Annual inflation of 4%
means that a basket of goods that can be bought for $100 on January
1 costs $104 on December 31. But if during that year you put $100
in a savings account paying 8%, your balance at the en dof that year
woul dbe $108. Left uninvested, that $100 woul ecline in pur-
chasing power to about $96, whereas the investe damount gives you
a purchasing power of about $104 (the $108 you have less the impact
on its buying power of the 4% inflation).

These macroeconomic factors bear on value. Tax an dinflation
in particular determine how much your gross return will give you in
increase dpurchasing power. Changes in interest rates require revis-
ing any valuations made under different interest rate assumptions.
Operating as a business analyst requires knowledge of these things

104 Show Me the Money

but not their prediction. As Buffett says, “We do not have, never
have had, an dnever will have an opinion about where the stock
market, interest rates, or business activity will be a year from now.”4
Still, you can’t avoi deating a little spinach in the enterprise of in-
vesting. Those who dine on the business investor’s rigorous diet
emerge more muscular an dfit from the meal. Course two is serve
up next.


C h a p t e r 7

YOUR CIRCLE OF
COMPETENCE

nvestors avoi dstocks outside their circle of competence; those
who buy stocks outside their circle of competence are gamblers,
I
speculators, or fools. If you lack the grounds for understanding a
business—grounds ultimately for estimating a gap between value
an dprice—but make a purchase anyway, you may as well be at a
Las Vegas or Atlantic City blackjack table or a local poker party. All
you are really doing is guessing, hoping, maybe even praying that
things work out your way. Yet there is little reason, other than dumb
luck, to think they will.
The first thing you must do before investing in any business is
make sure you have a basic understanding of that business. This
requires some familiarity with its products, customers, selling envi-
ronment, an dso on—in short, its operating climate.
It is quite a different proposition to understan dbusinesses, such
as Procter & Gamble, that make an dsell a wide variety of familiar
consumer products such as peanut butter, soap, an dtoothpaste than
it is to understan dbusinesses, such as Applie dMaterials, that make
an dsell a wide variety of highly technical materials for the semicon-
ductor industry such as expitaxial an dpolysilicon deposition, etch,
ion, implantation, an dmetrology (understand?).
Getting the information necessary to determine whether a busi-
ness is within your circle of competence before making an invest-
ment decision is easy. Check out the SEC-maintaine dFree-
Edgar.com Web site or contact the SEC at its Washington, D.C., or
various regional offices. Or check out each company’s Web site di-
rectly. You can even search the SEC Edgar database on lots of other
Web sites, including 10kwizard.com, Edgarspace, an dEdgaronline.
Fin dthe section in the company’s annual report calle dmanage-
ment’s discussion an danalysis of the business. This is a narrative
assessment of the business that shoul dhelp an dtest your under-

105

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


106 Show Me the Money

standing of it. Another useful source to consult is the chairman’s or
CEO’s letter, as much for what it says as for what it does not say
about the business. You will learn an enormous amount by reading
just a few of these reports, an dthe more you read, the better able
you will be to evaluate them.

THE INITIAL CIRCLE

Circles of competence shoul dbe drawn according to your ability an
willingness to understan da business an dits operating climate. Your
circle’s boundaries are define dby your knowledge an daptitude; its
contents are companies about which you can make an intelligent
investment decision in light of those boundaries. Omit from your
circle businesses that are too har dfor you to understan dor that
change too rapidly for you to keep up with.
To define your circle of competence, start with your own indus-
try. Retail store managers probably have a hea dstart in understand-
ing CVS, Walgreen’s, Gap, an dHome Depot; restaurant employees,
in understanding McDonald’s. People in the energy business ten
to know that business an dwill have a leg up on Exxon-Mobil, Enron,
an dTexaco. Engineers an dscientists will have a better shot at un-
derstanding Dow Chemical an dDuPont, an dtelecommunications
devotees have a goo dshot at MCI, AT&T, an dLucent. Doctors
shoul dcertainly have an edge in evaluating pharmaceutical concerns
such as Eli Lilly an dPfizer. Farmers may be able to evaluate John
Deere better than the average Wall Street banker can.
Think also about the things you buy an duse an dhow you do
so. You may know more about companies such as American Home
Products, BMW, Federal Express, an dSony than you think, or at
least you may be able to understan dthem better than you think. Try
Hershey’s an dNestle' if you are a chocolate lover, Anheuser-Busch
or Heineken if you drink a lot of beer, an dTiffany’s if diamonds are
your best friend.
Do the same with regional companies in your area. Public util-
ities such as ConE din New York an dBlack Hills in the Rocky Moun-
tains (South Dakota, Wyoming, an dMontana) an dregional banks
such as First Oaks in Chicago, Wilshire in Los Angeles, an dAlabama
National in the Southeast (Alabama, Georgia, an dFlorida) shoul
be easy an dinteresting to examine for people living in those areas.
So too are similarly locate dlarger companies, say, Boeing in Seattle,


Your Circle of Competence 107

Coca-Cola in Atlanta, Kimberly-Clark in Dallas, an dJohnson Con-
trols in Milwaukee.
How do the companies which seem a natural fit for your circle
of competence relate to less obvious ones that fit just as well? If you
are in retail, what about apparel companies such as Gucci, Polo
Ralph Lauren, an dHe`rmes International? Up-and-comers such as
Kenneth Cole? Sports fans may enjoy learning more about Nike;
musicians, Steinway. The examples pour out if you identify the sector
your business or interests are in an dcomb through lists of compa-
nies in that sector publishe dby all the major investment banking
firms an davailable on many reputable Web sites.
To sharpen your boundaries after you’ve identifie done or a few
companies an dindustries you know something about, evaluate
whether a particular company qualifies for admission by asking your-
self a series of commonsense questions about that business. If you
can answer them, the company probably qualifies; if you can’t, pick
another one that stands a better chance an dask the same questions.
Here are the key questions.
What products does the company sell or services does it provide?
There is a big difference between razors (Gillette) an dcomputer
chips (Intel) an dcruises (Carnival). Do you understan dthese prod-
ucts an dhow they are used?
Does the company make products that people need? Razors an
chips almost certainly, but that’s less true of luxury goods such as
cruise vacations. Will these products probably be neede dfor the
indefinite future? There are big differences between toothpaste
(Colgate-Palmolive), paper (Mead), an dpet rocks (who made
them?). Big differences can arise between today’s needs an dtomor-
row’s (razors can become obsolete with an explosion of electrolysis
or laser removal, an dcomputer chips may be displace dby chemical-
driven substitutes now in the research stage).
How distinctive is the company’s product compare dto possible
substitutes for it? The difference between Coke an dPepsi may be
slight, but do consumers think it matters? Product differentiation in
the beverage industry, as in many other consumer product busi-
nesses, can be remarkably successful.
Aske danother way, how likely is it that this company can raise
prices on its products without losing unit volume in sales? Carnival
might be able to do that with its cruises more easily than Mea dcan
with its paper. The ability to raise prices without hurting sales is
calle deconomic goodwill. Some companies get more of it by distin-


108 Show Me the Money

guishing their products in the consumer’s eye as having distinctive
traits that make them worth buying even at higher prices. Bang &
Olufsen di dthis successfully in upgrading its image to a maker of
stereos an dother soun dsystems at the “high end” of audio tech-
nology.
Procee dwith similar sorts of questions about the product mar-
ket. What is the company’s target customer and/or client base? Is it
teens an dpreteens (say, electronic music) or retirees (medical de-
vices), male or female (sporting goods, clothing, cosmetics)?
Does the company depen don one or a few customers for a major
portion of its revenues, as might a manufacturer or wholesaler such
as Procter & Gamble (13% of sales go to Wal-Mart)? Does it have
millions of customers, or does it depen don a handful? (Coca-Cola
has over 14 million customers who sell in turn to the ultimate con-
sumer!)
How much does any dependency matter—how sturdy is a major
customer? Even businesses with well-known an dtime-teste dprod-
ucts can suffer enormous economic damage from policy changes by
their major customers. Mattel (with its venerable Barbie line) an
Hasbro (with powerful brande dproducts such as Star Wars an dPo-
ke'mon figures) both took major financial beatings when one of their
largest customers—Toys-“R”-Us—force dmajor inventory control
changes that shifte dmuch of the cost of carrying inventory from the
store to the manufacturers.
How does the company sell its products? Direct mail (say, Dell)
an dstorefronts (say, Starbucks) are quite distinct modes of distri-
bution, an deach differs again from sales over the Internet (say, Am-
azon.com) or sales by industrial manufacturers to their industrial
clients (say, Johnson Controls an dGeneral Electric).
What is the company’s geographic market? An economic down-
turn in Asia can severely impair profits at multinational companies
that do significant parts of their business there, as the crisis in 1998
showe dfor venerable companies such as Procter & Gamble an
Coca-Cola. Yet both also ha dsuch global reach, they survive dwith
no long-term damage.
Has the company le dor at least adapte dquickly to changing
economic an dbusiness conditions? Companies able to maneuver
quickly to join their ol deconomy businesses with new economy
strategies—such as General Electric—deserve credit for that deft-
ness. Can you judge which ones can do this?
These commonsense questions can go on an don to include
questions such as the following: What is the company’s supply sit-


Your Circle of Competence 109

uation like? Its employee relations? Does it operate in regions subject
to ordinary or extraordinary risks of political or economic instability?
Grappling with these questions shoul dbe enough to test whether
a company is within your circle of competence. Again, if you can
answer these questions, the company probably qualifies; if you can’t,
try one you are more familiar with.
Graham advised: “The fiel dof choice is wide; the selection
shoul epen dnot only on the individual’s competence an dequip-
ment but perhaps equally well upon his interests an dpreferences.”1
Buffett echoes the point: “You don’t have to be an expert on every
company, or even many. You only have to be able to evaluate com-
panies within your circle of competence. The size of that circle is
not very important; knowing its boundaries, however, is vital.”2 If
you have to choose between a large circle an da thick boundary,
choose the latter. But a bigger circle will give you more opportuni-
ties, so work on enlarging it.

THE NURTURED CIRCLE

The boundaries of your circle must change over time. If you leave
them the same, some companies will simply disappear. If you are a
master of the fashion industry today—say you work in New York
City’s garment industry or are a buyer for a large retail chain such
as Sak’s Fifth Avenue—you know that to remain a master five years
from now you will nee dto learn new things over that period. Indeed,
particularly in the fashion industry, you nee dto keep up daily, since
fashion is (by its very name) a business that swiftly an dconstantly
evolves. Colors, hemlines, cuts, an dwho’s in an dwho’s out change
by the season. To stay on top, you must change.
If you simply took what you knew about an industry you worke
in ten years ago an duse dthat knowledge to evaluate a company
in that industry today, you woul dbe at a severe disadvantage. Take
the business of book publishing, which has change drapidly in that
period. In the distribution channels, for example, first the rise of
chain booksellers such as Barnes & Noble an dBorders eclipse
much of the power of the old-fashione dindependent booksellers;
then the rise of on-line booksellers such as Amazon.com altere dthe
dynamic again. An dthe entire book publishing industry has consol-
idate dsubstantially an dbecome part of a broader entertainment in-
dustry.
Anyone in the publishing industry during that perio dneede dto


110 Show Me the Money

constantly stretch her knowledge of that industry an din doing so
redefine her investment circle of competence. If an editor, publisher,
or other industry member simply stuck with only what she knew in
the beginning, she riske dlosing not only power in her job but in-
vestment insight into her industry as well. If you stop learning now,
you will know less as the worl dchanges. An das the worl dchanges,
you nee dto know more just to stay in the same place.
Those who can discern trends in their industries are better able
to ascertain which businesses in an industry are likely to remain or
emerge as leaders. Equally important is recognizing that industries
you know can be affecte dby other industries about which you know
less. In book publishing, putting 4-pound, 3-inch volumes on tape
or compact disc (CD) create dcompetition for the music industry—
people listen to books in their cars an deven at home instea dof
listening to music. Turning multivolume encyclopedia sets into the
single-disc CD-ROM format sucke da huge chunk of the profit out
of the traditional print encyclopedia business.
To maintain your circle of competence in the face of invasions
an dforce dchange from other industries thus requires that you know
something about those other industries. That calls not merely for a
commitment to maintain your circle of competence as the things in
it change but for constantly stretching your circle of competence to
include things that might affect it.
Some people were raise din tech environments an dknow more
about computers, digitalization, an dthe Internet than they know
about fashion an dpublishing. Companies in those industries may
dominate their initial circle of competence. However, sticking to
those industries alone is dangerous. A tech company’s value will be
affecte dby how its products are use dby other industries, such as
fashion an dpublishing.
Likewise, those who work in industries such as fashion an dpub-
lishing may know more about those fields than about anything tech-
related, an dtheir initial circle of competence will be fille dwith com-
panies in that cohort. But if they don’t learn something about the
tech businesses that drive changes in fashion an dpublishing, they
will know less about fashion an dpublishing too.
All companies an dindustries are expose dto change from outside
forces. Among those forces are globalization, computerization, an
the rise of the service sector in the Unite dStates an dof e-business
globally. Keeping up with such developments helps gauge their prob-
able impact. Other external forces are much harder to measure, such


Your Circle of Competence 111

as war, trade disputes, oil price spikes, an dearthquakes. This calls
for a delicate balance.
Graham advise dthat “there are other factors outside the control
of the company that are perhaps equally important in their influence
on the value of its securities. The outlook for the industry, general
business an dsecurity-market conditions, periods of inflation or de-
pression, artificial market influences, the popular favor of the type
of security—these factors cannot be measure din terms of exact ra-
tios an dmargins of safety. They can only be judge dby a general
knowledge gaine dby constant contact with financial an dbusiness
news.”3
Buffett appreciates this too but emphasizes selecting businesses
that will prosper despite these things, an dnever indulging the fan-
tasy of being able to see into the crystal ball:

We will continue to ignore political an deconomic forecasts,
which are an expensive distraction for many investors an dbusi-
nessmen. Thirty years ago, no one coul dhave foreseen the huge
expansion of the Vietnam War, wage an dprice controls, two oil
shocks, the resignation of a president, the dissolution of the
Soviet Union, a one-day drop in the Dow of 508 points, or trea-
sury bill yields fluctuating between 2.8% an d17.4%
But, surprise—none of these blockbuster events made the
slightest dent in Ben Graham’s investment principles. . . . Fear
is the foe of the fa ist, but the frien dof the fundamentalist.
A different set of major shocks is sure to occur in the next
30 years. We will neither try to predict these nor to profit from
them.4

All companies—whether classic, vintage, or rookie—are subject
to change in character an dquality. Classics with rising sales an
earnings can face contractions an dreversals from competitors, new
entrants, downturns in important markets, or changes in the way
their customers or suppliers do business in the face of changes.
Rookies with low sales an dno earnings can come to dominate an
industry, throttle the competition, an dultimately generate enormous
earnings an dvalue. Vintage companies can go either way.
Even if all businesses change, some businesses enjoy one thing
that does not change: the reasons their customers keep coming back.
Companies like that in your circle deserve careful attention; they are
so rare an dvaluable that Buffett calls them the Inevitables.5
In maintaining an dstretching your circle of competence, note


112 Show Me the Money

how changes that affect industries an dcompanies follow certain
pretty well define dpaths. Business change is not unpredictable, only
har dto predict. There are myria dtypes of business changes an
patterns that they follow, but the infinite potential variation can be
organize dpretty simply to enable you to think about those changes
in a profitable way. The chief patterns that matter relate to products
an dtheir degree of bran dor commodity characteristics, the sources
an dcosts of supply, the chain of distribution, customers’ habits an
tastes, an dbusiness an dorganizational design.6
Take the brand-commodity pattern. Some businesses are able to
transform a commodity product into a brande dproduct, as Clorox
di dwith bleach an dFrank Perdue di dwith chicken. Those brande
products can be retransforme dback into commodity products, going
the way of the Model T an dthe Hoover vacuum, or at least have
the franchise value of the bran dreduced, as occurre dwith the Xerox
machine an dCampbell’s Soup. Knowledge of a company’s bran
position is important, but more important is knowing its commit-
ment an dability to promote, protect, an dexpan dthat position.
Supply patterns either reduce or enlarge the amount of inventory
a company has to maintain. Companies that reduce their inventory
en dup decreasing their costs an dboosting profits. Dell develope
close relationships with its suppliers that enable dit to pretty much
eliminate carrying inventory of any of the computer components it
uses. IBM an dCompaq have ha dless success in doing that.
Distribution patterns are always important an dgot a huge
amount of attention during the dawn of the Internet. The direct
seller of products has come an dgone over the years. The Fuller
brush salesman, the milkman, an dthe Avon lady use dto give a goo
profit advantage to their companies, but the shift to suburban living
an dthe proliferation of cars, highways, shopping centers, an dmalls
change dall that. Some of that change dagain as direct sellers re-
emerge dto bring computers, books, an deven groceries direct to the
home.
Customers’ tastes obviously relate to distribution patterns,
though the causality is not always certain. As they say in marketing,
if you make it, people will come (an dif you deliver it, people may
take it). But consumer tastes an dhabits are equally obviously an
enormous driver of profits an da determinant of where the profit
centers are. It is useful to distinguish here, however, between fa
patterns an dlonger-term patterns.
Silly products that capture the temporary imagination of the


Your Circle of Competence 113

masses may generate some short-term profit (hula hoops, yo-yos),
but the typical pattern is that those tastes evaporate an dthe profit
in them moves to the collectors an ealers (Pez candy dispensers).
The patterns of endurance give rise to longer-term profit centers, as
with the tren dtowar dlow-salt an dlow-fat foods that companies
such as Nabisco took advantage of.
Business organization an esign move aroun da lot with
changes in the context in which companies operate an dcompete:

• Globalization le dmany companies, such as Procter & Gamble an
Xerox, to reorganize their management structures—from having
heads of different parts of the worl dto having heads of various
product lines throughout the world.
• The rise of the Internet an de-commerce le dmany to create entire
new dimensions of their businesses to market product on-line or
to redirect major chunks of their businesses to take advantage of
the lower costs an dwider reach of Internet sales—in GE’s case,
the company di dboth.
• The move towar dservice profit centers an dthe ability to unleash
greater profits with fewer har dassets le dmany companies to op-
erate parts of their businesses as managers under contract rather
than through outright ownership, the way Barnes & Noble entere
the college bookstore market.

Companies that adapt organizational structure an dbusiness de-
sign to meet changing needs an dopportunities are goo dcompanies
to keep an eye on. If you notice a company that constantly readapts
itself in this way, try to learn more about it. Even if those companies
don’t make it into your circle of competence, you can enlarge it with
the knowledge you gain from studying them. Coca-Cola an dDisney
are goo dexamples.
Coca-Cola’s main business is selling beverages globally, princi-
pally gallons of concentrates an dsyrups that constitute the Coke
bran dbut also Minute Mai dan dnearly two hundre dothers. Coca-
Cola devotes most of its resources to marketing its brands to pro-
mote consumer awareness an dmaintaining an dexpanding its bot-
tling operations through a mix of independent bottlers an dwholly
or partly owne dbottlers. Coca-Cola reinvente ditself in the 1980s to
see its chief customers not as those who actually drink Coke an
the other brands but the distributors aroun dthe worl dwho carry
product to those en dconsumers (this transformation was le dby


114 Show Me the Money

Coca-Cola’s late CEO, Roberto Goizueta, who is discusse dfurther
in the final chapter of this book).
Disney’s segments are mainly creative content (films, animation,
books), broadcasting through the American Broadcasting Corpora-
tion (ABC) an dESPN, an dtheme parks an dresorts. A unique thing
about Disney is that going to Disneylan dan dDisney Worl d(with
children or grandchildren especially) is an incomparable experience.
An dDisney constantly reinvigorates its business by expanding into
television, building blockbuster products that can be sol din multiple
forms (film, record, tape, theme park, apparel, an dsouvenirs), an
so on, an dby exploiting the Internet to broaden both its content an
its distribution channels.
By no means an exhaustive list of patterns, these are the kinds
of important trends that alter an dreshape circles of competence an
that must be looke dafter to expan dyour circle. To sharpen your
idea of what you shoul dknow about companies in order for them
to qualify as members of your circle of competence, let’s take a
closer look at some candidates.

A FULL CIRCLE

Take one company from each of the categories mentione din the
beginning: the classic General Electric (GE), the vintage Microsoft,
an dthe rookie Amazon.com. These are all important companies an
are widely discusse din the financial press, but they differ in age,
products, an dfinancial an dbusiness characteristics.
GE operates through numerous divisions in a wide range of in-
dustries. The most important divisions are appliances such as refrig-
erators, lighting such as lamps an dbulbs, the National Broadcasting
Corporation (NBC), aircraft engines, capital services (itself a widely
diversifie dgroup of about thirty businesses engage din various con-
sumer an dcommercial financing activities worldwide), plastics use
in a wide range of applications from cars to CD-ROMs, an dindus-
trial, medical, power, an dtransportation systems (including products
an dbusiness solutions such as factory automation, surgical diag-
nostics, gas turbines, an dlocomotives, respectively).
Understanding all of GE is a tall order that calls for some ap-
preciation of the basics of finance, broadcasting, consumer, an din-
dustrial businesses. But if you rea dits annual report for the last few
years an dpay special attention to the excellent letters written by


Your Circle of Competence 115

CEO Jack Welch (discusse din Chapter 14), you will gain a goo
sense of the company an dhow it operates. Indeed, Welch argues
that understanding GE is not a tall order at all, an dafter you rea
Chapter 14, you may agree.
One thing that immediately jumps out at you is that GE got to
where it is through Welch’s declaration 20 years ago that the com-
pany woul dremain in any business only if it were the number one
or number two player in that business. Businesses that di dnot
achieve that rank were fixed, sold, or closed. The company has ende
up the business equivalent of a magnificent art collection, Jack
Welch, curator.
Founde din 1975, Microsoft is a relative newcomer compare dto
the century-ol dGE. It develops, manufactures, licenses, an dsup-
ports a range of software products, including operating systems,
server applications, worker productivity applications, an dsoftware
development tools. Microsoft’s success woul dhave been har dto pre-
dict in the mi le to late 1980s, when the dynamic of the software
industry was uncertain. As that decade came an dwent an dthe 1990s
confirme dthe power an dimportance of that industry, the company’s
dominant position became easier to predict.
Yet pervasive an dwidesprea dInternet use in the late 1990s might
have pose da threat to Microsoft’s business, though a threat it man-
age dto navigate (excuse the pun, but it is an apt characterization)
through its aggressive entry into an dforceful presence in the Inter-
net browser industry. While it is a somewhat older business than
Amazon.com, its relative youth compare dto GE makes its future
(wholly apart from its legal an dregulatory environment) harder to
predict than that of its classic elders.
Still, you can learn from its annual report that Microsoft’s Win-
dows operating system is installe don more than 300 million Intel-
base dpersonal computers (PCs), making it the world’s leading PC
software company. It is also a leader in PC application tools an dhas
grown rapidly to rank among the top networks on the Internet. Its
properties receive over 40 million unique monthly visitors to sites
such as Hotmail, MSNBC, Carpoint, an dMoneyCentral. If these
computing an dInternet operations are up your alley, rea dabout Mi-
crosoft’s stuff in its annual report an dCEO Bill Gates’s books or
annual letters to shareholders.
Amazon.com is a business infant begun in 1994, retailing on-line
books, CDs, an dvideos an doffering some 5 million titles. Its busi-
ness model, while interesting, is har dto pin down because it con-


116 Show Me the Money

stantly an drapidly evolves. Amazon.com starte das a bookseller but
quickly expande dinto a wide range of product lines such as toys,
electronics, home improvement, an deven a joint venture with Soth-
eby’s auction house. It attracts an average of as many as 12 million
unique monthly visitors to its site.
Amazon.com buys inventory from suppliers on a just-in-time ba-
sis, thus minimizing its inventory an dwarehousing costs, an dtakes
orders on its state-of-the-art Web site for shipping by its warehouse
teams. Whatever one thinks of this business model, it depends en-
tirely on the continuing success an dproliferation of the Internet as
an important way of doing consumer shopping.
While so far so good, the Internet’s brief history makes fore-
casting the future of Amazon.com an dother e-businesses more dif-
ficult for most people than it is to forecast the future of companies
such as GE an deven Microsoft. Indeed, it is also difficult because
Amazon.com has never generate da profit. The book business is ma-
ture, slow-growing, an dfiercely competitive an dhas low profit mar-
gins; Amazon.com’s expansion into other businesses poses huge
start-up costs that will deepen those losses further in the short run,
though they may come roaring back in the form of huge profits in
the future.
Amazon.com’s growing diversity of businesses can fragment
managerial attention (much as your diversifie dportfolio can distract
you). If well managed, though, they coul dbe as successful a group
as GE’s varie dlot. Despite the uncertainties, Amazon.com’s business
is intriguing. Those with the ability to learn more about it an dan
aptitude for understanding it woul dbe foolish not to look a little
harder.

DECISION MAKING

Assessing information about a business an dits industry an drelate
industries enables you to make rational judgments about the prob-
able payoffs versus the probable losses. Anything less is simply a toss
of the dice. Conservative decision makers take the position that no
option shoul dbe pursue dwithout a high level of positive evidence
an dinformation. To put a number on it, they might argue that you
must have a degree of confidence in your judgment of, say, 90% (you
are 90% sure of the outcome an d10% unsure).
Less conservative people believe that the level of evidence re-


Your Circle of Competence 117

quire dfor a particular decision varies with the probable payoff from
being right compare dto the probable loss from being wrong.7 If the
payoff from being right is very high compare dto the loss from being
wrong (say, gaining $99 versus losing $1), this view says you can
reduce the require dconfidence level substantially—maybe to as low
as 1%. People who buy lottery tickets reflect this kin dof decision
making.
If the gain-loss matrix goes the other way (say, gaining only $1
versus losing $99), then you woul dinsist on a much greater confi-
dence level—maybe nearly 100%. These are the sure bets in life. An
as even the most steadfast gambler knows, there is no such thing as
a sure bet.
Your risk appetite will determine the sort of decision maker that
best suits your own psychology. Losses are inevitable. If they make
your misery index soar, stick with conservative approaches; if you
can tolerate them, a more aggressive approach is defensible. (Be-
ware: most people weigh losses more heavily than gains by a factor
of about 2.5.)
Buffett is a conservative decision maker. Explaining Berkshire’s
conservative financial policy of using little debt, Buffett says that if
there were a 99% probability that higher leverage woul dproduce
something goo dan da 1% chance of a surprise that woul dproduce
something between anguish an efault, he woul dnot bite that bul-
let: “We wouldn’t have like dthose 99:1 o s—an dnever will. A small
chance of distress or disgrace cannot, in our view, be offset by a
large chance of extra returns.”8
Graham was also cautious, warning investors to avoi dventures
with little to gain an dmuch to lose.9 He advise dforming judgments
on the basis of knowledge an dexperience, not on the basis of opti-
mism (valuable in many settings but not in investing; Buffett calls
optimism the “enemy of the rational buyer”).10
Graham an dBuffett’s views reflect contemporary social psy-
chology. Research in this fiel dshows that in any decision-making
process, the cognitive weaknesses share dby most people produce
subconscious errors of judgment. The main cognitive biases in rea-
soning that investors nee dto worry about are the following:

• Overconfidence and superiority: believing you are certain when
you are only pretty sure (or believing you are pretty sure when you
are uncertain) an dbelieving you are better than average (the Lake
Woebegon syndrome).


118 Show Me the Money

• Confirmation and resistance: skewing your interpretation of new
information to support earlier beliefs an dbeing slow to update
those beliefs.
• Vividness and pattern seeking: weighing dramatic information too
heavily an doverreacting to a series of similar sorts of news items
in the belief that they show a pattern.11

Of these, the most potentially damaging cognitive biases are
overconfidence an dsuperiority. As Buffett advises: “What counts for
most people in investing is not how much they know, but rather how
realistically they define what they don’t know. An investor needs to
do very few things right as long as he or she avoids big mistakes.”12
There are three simple strategies to help investors avoi dthese
reasoning errors. The first is to recognize them. The secon dis to
insist on a justification, something you can do by writing a memo to
yourself about why you are making a decision. (Beware of the traps
of this strategy, which Buffett illustrates by quoting Ben Franklin:
“So convenient a thing it is to be a reasonable creature, since it
enables one to fin dor make a reason for everything one has a min
to do.”13 Many people do not have articulable reasons for many of
their decisions. In investing decisions, if you don’t have one, don’t
try to make one up.) The third, an drelated, strategy is to have clear
guidance in your decision making. For investing, this includes the
ideas discusse din this book.


C h a p t e r 8

RECOGNIZING
SUCCESS

hat makes an investment attractive? A price substantially
Wlower than value. Estimating value requires making judgments
about probable future performance, but the only available basis for
prognosis is the recor dof the past. The historian Daniel Boorstein
likene dplanning for the future without knowing some history to
planting cut flowers.
Investments cannot be made on the basis of such temporary gar-
dens either but require a look at the history of business. If account-
ing is the language of business, numbers are its history. Just as his-
tory is complex, broad, an dreplete with contradictions, so too are
the numbers of business history. If you focus on a few key numbers,
however, the roa dmap to goo dinvestment selection becomes clear.
Start with the management’s discussion an danalysis of the busi-
ness. In a ition to a narrative assessment of the business, this sum-
marizes the most important numbers in the company’s financial
statements. So you don’t have to go to the trouble of doing the
calculations—just look them up. This discussion also interprets the
meaning of those numbers from management’s perspective. So you
also don’t have to become an expert in accounting to make sense of
this stuff.
Beware of using secondhan atabases. Lots of Web sites give
you a chance to employ screening tools to search through 12,000 or
more different businesses with dozens of different variables of the
kin escribe dbelow. These tools operate as filters to give you a
limite dnumber of businesses to examine more closely. In principle,
this is precisely the kin dof technique that is sensible to use.
However, you cannot be sure the search engines are working
with data of integrity. The data do not usually include information
about a company’s accounting policies, footnote information, or
management’s discussion an danalysis. The data are not always up-

119

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


120 Show Me the Money

date dor corrected, may have embe e derrors that arise in the trans-
mission process, an dmay be the product of aggregating information
that is dissimilar or noncomparable. This is not to say that these
systems are worthless, only that you shoul dexercise care in using
them.1

BUSINESS FUEL

Every business has debts coming due every day which require re-
sources to meet. The difference between short-term needs an dre-
sources is calle dworking capital. It is a bit like fuel in an engine; it
is better to have a full tank, but overfilling can be dangerous. Too
little working capital can pose a threat to the ability of a company
to operate in the ordinary course over the immediate future, but too
much working capital can mean that resources are not being de-
ploye din optimal ways.
The right level of working capital varies across businesses. One
way to determine how much working capital is neede dan dassess
its adequacy is to compare the working capital to sales. Typically, a
retailing business that generates substantial sales of low-cost items,
such as a supermarket, needs less working capital per dollar of sales
(perhaps aroun d10 to 15%) than does an industrial manufacturer of
high-ticket items such as airplanes (perhaps aroun d25 to 35%). A
manufacturer of consumer goods—say, Carnation or Clorox—might
require some level in between.
Other businesses can operate with low or even negative working
capital. Companies in the restaurant business, McDonald’s, for ex-
ample, often operate with negative working capital because of the
cash nature of the business. This system provides direct liquidity,
an dpayment terms with suppliers usually permit payment after prod-
uct is both receive dan duse din the business to generate cash. Com-
panies in other industries can benefit from the same combination,
as Amazon.com aptly demonstrates by operating sometimes with
negative working capital without apparent impairment of its ability
to meet obligations as they come due.
In the oil an dgas industry, a principal source of cash is prove
reserves that are produce din the ensuing year. While they cannot
be reporte das working capital on the balance sheet under generally
accepte daccounting principles, they are turne dinto cash. Compa-
nies in other industries sometimes fun dnew construction by issuing


Recognizing Success 121

short term obligations such as commercial paper that is later refi-
nance dwith long-term obligations such as bank loans. This can also
produce low or negative working capital while not posing any threat
to the company’s short-term ability to meet its obligations.
Ben Graham put it this way in his marvelous little book pub-
lishe din 1937, The Interpretation of Financial Statements:

The proper amount of working capital require dby a particular
enterprise will depen dupon both the amount an dthe character
of its business. The chief point of comparison is the amount of
working capital per dollar of sales. A company doing business
for cash an denjoying a rapi dturnover of inventory—for exam-
ple, a chain grocery enterprise—needs a much lower working
capital compare dwith sales than does the manufacturer of
heavy machinery sol don long-term payments.2

Current and Quick Ratios

Evaluating the working capital position is achieve dby comparing the
relationship between current assets an dcurrent liabilities in relative
terms. Known as the current ratio, this relationship shows how many
dollars in cash or other assets likely to be turne dinto cash within a
year are available to pay debts that are due within that year. As a
rule of thumb, for most businesses the ideal current ratio is aroun
1.5, but the range of current ratios across companies an dindustries
is broad.
A current ratio substantially higher—say, 3 or 4 or more—is a
sign of potential problems, not with respect to liquidity but with
respect to efficiency. It implies that there are financial resources that
coul dbe free dup an dput to better use: Inventory coul dbe reduced,
receivables coul dbe collecte dmore quickly or sold, or payables
coul dbe age da bit more before being paid.
At the other extreme, a current ratio of 1 or less (i.e., negative
working capital) is often a warning signal that a company may face
difficulties in paying its debts as they come due in the short term.
As the ratio gets close to 1 or below it, therefore, investigate the
liquidity question further.
Recently the average current ratio of the companies in the S&P
500 was about 1.5, about the same as for the conglomerate segment
of that index, of which GE is a part. The current ratio in the com-
puter industry tends to be higher, closer to 2.75 (with Microsoft right
aroun dthat average). Specialty retailers, including Amazon.com, ha


122 Show Me the Money

higher current ratios than these, aroun d3.5, with Amazon.com’s
fluctuating from negative to 4.5, depending on its borrowing levels
for investment in new businesses.
This range of ratios reflects different corporate needs as well as
unique funding situations (calle dthe net trade cycle, or the rela-
tionship between desire dinvestment in inventory compare dto the
relationship between credit extende dan dcredit taken). Amazon.com
has at times operate dwith negative working capital, which, given
the retail nature of its business with low inventory an dlow accounts
receivable, is safe an dindee da goo dindicator of value from man-
aging working capital. Microsoft’s relatively high ratio is due in large
part to the fact that it generates enormous amounts of cash in its
operations. GE an dits peers exhibit the usual characteristics of rel-
atively mature businesses, though GE constantly tries to reduce the
amount of working capital it requires to zero.
You can fine-tune your analysis even more by looking only to
highly liqui dassets, excluding assets such as inventory an dprepai
expenses. This leaves cash (liquidity itself) an dassets such as ac-
counts receivable that are due in shorter periods (say, within three
months). This more refine dtest is known as the quick ratio an
sometimes (equivalently) as either the liquidity ratio or the acid test
ratio.
Rules of thumb still apply. A minimum quick ratio of 1 is desir-
able, an dhigher ratios are generally better—up to a point. This is
useful to know because of what it reveals about the relative level of
the current ratio. For example, a current ratio within a seemingly
satisfactory range (say, between 1.4 an d2) coul dactually be high
largely as a result of excessive inventory levels. Since a business can-
not pay debts with inventory, there is reason to worry about a com-
pany’s ability to pay its debts as they come due if it has a low quick
ratio even while sporting a high current ratio.
Conglomerates such as GE ten dto have a relatively wider gap
than do other businesses between the current ratio an dthe quick
ratio. As a segment, the conglomerate current ratio of aroun d1.5,
compare dto a quick ratio of about .8, reflects the fact that most of
the current assets are neither cash nor short-term accounts receiv-
able. The ban dis tighter in the more liqui dbusinesses of computers
an don-line retail sales, where there are speedier assets in the cur-
rent ratio (2.75 an d2.6 in the computer industry an dabout 3.5 an
2.5 in the specialty retailer segment). These variations reflect the
range of operating environments in these businesses an dalso show


Recognizing Success 123

that neither GE, Microsoft, nor Amazon.com is all that different
from its segment in terms of liquidity needs or how they are being
met.

Debt

Check out a company’s ability to attract a itional financing; this is
particularly important when a company has negative working capital
from issuing short-term obligations such as commercial paper. This
is done by using the debt-to-equity ratio. In its most general formu-
lation, the calculation is the ratio between the total debt of a com-
pany, including short-term debt as well as long-term debt, divide
by the amount of owners’ equity.
The ratio measures the relative borrowing capacity an ebt-
paying ability of the enterprise over the long term. Businesses with
relatively high debt-to-equity ratios are characterize das “highly lev-
eraged,” meaning that the debt level in relation to the investment
level of the owners in the business (the shareholders) is very high.
What levels of debt-to-equity ratios are normal has varie dhistori-
cally, in accordance with economic conditions an dcollective beliefs
about credit.
During the 1980s, for example, debt-to-equity ratios in the range
of 7:1 or higher were common, whereas during the early 1990s the
typical ratios were closer to 4:1. At the turn of the twenty-first cen-
tury, the debt-to-equity ratio of the S&P 500 average djust about 1:
1, reflecting a decade in which most business financing was done
using equity rather than debt.
Conglomerates still are relatively debt-heavy, however, with the
segment average of about 3:1 an dGE above that segment average
with a debt-to-equity ratio of aroun d4:1. That level reflects the rel-
atively more mature stage of these companies, particularly compare
with the far leaner computer industry. Microsoft, for example, funds
all its operations with internally generate dcash, enabling it to op-
erate with no debt whatsoever, an dthe average debt-to-equity ratio
for the computer industry as a whole is a staggeringly low .2:1. Am-
azon.com weighs in between these levels, reflecting both its nee dto
finance its expanding operations an dwarehouse construction pro-
jects an dits relatively lesser ability compare dwith Microsoft to gen-
erate sufficient cash to satisfy those needs.
Leverage reflecte din a relatively higher debt-to-equity ratio can
be desirable. If a company borrows at rates below what it can earn


124 Show Me the Money

on its capital, borrowing is profitable. Shareholders benefit. There is
a limit to the benefit, however, for even relatively cheap money must
be repai dan dtoo great a debt burden coul dbe crushing during
periods of depresse dreturns.
A way to gauge these trade-offs is to examine the coverage ra-
tio—a comparison of earnings to interest obligations on debt. For
most industrial companies, an interest coverage ratio in the range of
3 to 4 is considere dprudent an dimplies a relatively safe level of
borrowing. In light of the relatively low levels of indebtedness an
relatively high levels of profitability of corporate America at the turn
of the twenty-first century, the average interest coverage ratio among
the S&P 500 soare dto nearly 11.
Conglomerates remaine dclosest to historical norms, with GE’s
coverage ratio at about 2.5 an dthe segment at about 4.5. At nearly
the other extreme, Microsoft enjoys total coverage because it is sim-
ply debt-free. Amazon.com is an interesting case: Its coverage ratio
is negative because it is losing money (has negative profits), as low
as 4. That kin dof situation calls for looking more closely at other
fixe dcharges, which in Amazon.com’s case include leases on various
warehouses that also have to be paid. Its fixe dcharge coverage ratio
is therefore even worse, making its ability to generate a itional
funds to cover its increasing expansion all the more important.

MANAGERS UNDER THE MICROSCOPE

Three simple tools clue us into managerial effectiveness. They center
on the efficiency of inventory an dreceivables management an dthe
thickness of profit margins. Some companies report the spee dof
inventory an dreceivable turns an dthe levels of profit margins di-
rectly in their periodic reports, an dsome even highlight this in the
chairman’s letters—usually signs of goo dor at least honest manage-
ment. In other cases, you have to dig for it (not a goo dsign). Putting
managers under the microscope this way helps gauge the prospects
for future business performance—whether the maximal profits are
being squeeze dfrom the business or whether there is room for more.

Inventory Turns

While inventory is considere da current asset in that it is expecte
to be realize din cash within one year, you can be more precise about


Recognizing Success 125

its relative liquidity by measuring the spee dof its sale. Inventory
speed, or turns, is measure dby the relationship between the cost of
goods sol d(COGS) during a perio dan dthe average level of inven-
tory during that period:

Current year’s cost of goods sol
(Beginning inventory ending inventory)/2

Inventory turn levels are reliable indicators of the quality of in-
ventory management. The longer inventory sits aroun dwithout being
sold, the less value it a s to the business, since it coul dbe con-
verte dinto cash deploye dfor more productive uses. High inventory
levels also increase the risk of obsolescence or spoilage, require large
amounts of either cash or bank borrowing to finance, an dpose the
risk of loss if the market price at which they can be sol eclines
materially.
GE is well known for its inventory turn management, an dits
long-time CEO, Jack Welch, regularly reports this in his annual let-
ters. GE boasts inventory turns of a robust 8 ami da conglomerate
average inventory turn of about 7 though shy of the S&P 500 average
inventory turn of about 10. Microsoft manages inventory well too,
right along with the rest of the computer industry, with turns of
about 15; this is larger than GE in part because of the vastly different
products these businesses sell.
But Amazon.com is superefficient in inventory management, at
a breakneck pace of aroun d20. Amazon.com is a specialist in just-
in-time inventory, a key management strategy develope din the last
couple of decades that Amazon.com has taken to new levels. Stock
doesn’t sit idle in Amazon.com’s warehouses, an dthis swift turn-
over lowers costs. That enables the business either to charge lower
prices to its customers (hence Amazon.com’s aggressive pricing dis-
counts) or to continue to charge the market price but generate more
profit.

Receivable Turns

A company’s credit policies can be its Achilles’ heel or a driver of
efficiency. Too many sales on credit or too many delinquencies or
uncollectible accounts can crush cash flows. Speedy collection en-
hances liquidity an dcan enable a company to get its customers to
finance its business. Receivable turns are measure dby credit sales


126 Show Me the Money

(or total sales if those sales are not broken out separately) during a
perio ivide dby the average accounts receivable outstanding during
the period:

Credit sales
(Beginning accounts receivable ending accounts receivable)/ 2

To gauge the spee dof receivables collection, in turn, divide the
number of days in a year by the number of turns. The result gives
the average number of days the receivables are outstanding. Com-
pare that average to the business’s credit policies to see how well
managers are running the credit part of the business. There is trou-
ble if the average is greater than the policy (say, collections average
70 days but billing calls for payments to be made within 30 or 60
days).
GE displays considerable skill in receivables management, turn-
ing them about eight times per year, meaning they are collecte don
average within 45 days. That compares dramatically well to a con-
glomerate industry average of three turns, or 120 days. Microsoft is
also a speedy collector, turning receivables about 11 times a year, or
just over 30 days—perhaps as a result of its no-paper policy under
which all bills (an dinvoices) are complete delectronically—routing
a slower computer industry average that looks more like that of GE
(about eight turns, averaging 45 days).
Again, the exceptional case is Amazon.com, a standout in this
category, with about forty turns, or a mere nine days outstanding.
That means Amazon.com’s customers are funding a substantial part
of Amazon.com’s operations! They provide funds well ahea dof the
company’s obligations to pay its creditors, particularly its suppliers,
whose trade terms exten dup to 60 days.

Profit Margin

The key to business efficiency is the profit per dollar of sales, which
is calle dthe profit margin. To calculate it, divide operating income
by the total net sales (i.e., sales after returns, discounts, an dso on)
an dexpress the result as a percentage. (Two alternatives to this
standar dprofit margin calculation are also often made: A more
general one calle gross profit margin divides gross profit on sales
by total net sales, an da more specific one calle net profit margin


Recognizing Success 127

divides net income by total net sales.) The standar dway is as
follows:

Operating income
Net sales

There is tremendous variation in profit margins across industries.
Average profit margins in the automotive an dbanking industries, for
example, are way lower (often aroun d10%) than they are in the
computer, pharmaceutical, an dfoo dindustries (as high as 40% in
the case of Microsoft). The S&P 500 average profit margin is about
17.5%, right aroun dwhere GE stands, while other conglomerates
show margins of aroun d13 to 14%. Again, companies without earn-
ings, such as Amazon.com, have negative profit margins.
Profit margins can be squeeze dor expanded, depending in large
measure on whether a business has a special franchise that gives it
market power or competes in a commodity market where branding
an dproduct differentiation are harder. Coke an dPepsi constantly
pursue product differentiation to exploit the possibility of raising
prices without hurting unit volume, with varying degrees of success
in various economic climates.
Amazon.com invests heavily in this kin dof product differentia-
tion, with a state-of-the-art Web site that includes patente dfeatures
such as “one-click” an istinctive formatting. Yet competitors, in-
cluding barnesandnoble.com an dbuy.com, easily mimic much of this
would-be differentiation, quickly eroding profit margins.
The competition results in constant efforts to innovate an dad-
vance technology, whether in hamburger stands, on-line booksellers,
or the beverage industry. Such innovation tends to hurt rather than
help commodity businesses but benefits franchise businesses enor-
mously. That is why Microsoft so jealously guards the code to its
Windows operating system. It is why GE spends so many advertising
dollars on campaigns such as “We bring goo dthings to life,” in which
it highlights all dozen or so of its businesses without pitching par-
ticular products such as a washing machine or x-ray diagnostic
equipment.
When a company develops a superior production system for a
commodity product (such as oil), the bulk of the savings from that
system goes to consumers rather than to the company. In contrast,
a company that improves brande dgoods—those on which prices can


128 Show Me the Money

remain high or be raised—reaps most of the upside from that in-
novation. Profit margins are driven up or down depending on the
degree to which any business—whether GE, Microsoft, Ama-
zon.com, or any other company—can differentiate its products to
earn brande dpricing an dinnovation power or else be left to bear
the cross an dcosts of innovation.
A warning on profit margins is in order. Very high profit margins
may seem desirable an doften are, but they also invite competition
that coul estroy them. Very low profit margins are worth their
level. Something in between, towar dthe high end, is ideal.

BANG FOR THE BUCK

“Returns” are a measure of the bang a business gets for its buck.
The bang is always measure din terms of earnings. There are three
bases (or bucks) against which to measure the bang: equity, invest-
ment, an dassets.
In each measure, it is smart to gauge the return over a relatively
long perio dof time—say, five to ten years—rather than over short
periods to get a perspective that tracks a business’s ability to weather
the downsides an dreap the upsides.

Return on Equity

Return on equity is the amount a business earns on the capital
owne dby its shareholders. Shareholder capital is equal to the total
assets minus the total liabilities. If a business earns $10 million on
shareholder equity of $100 million, its return on equity is 10%.
Returns on equity were relatively high in the late 1990s an dearly
2000s. The S&P 500 average return on equity is aroun d22%. Below
that average are specialty retailers (15%, other than Amazon.com,
whose losses rather than profits give it a negative return on equity).
At or somewhat above the average are GE (about 27%) an dthe con-
glomerate sector (about 25%) as well as the computer industry at
about 25%. Leading the pack is Microsoft (about 34%).

Return on Investment

Return on investment is the amount a business earns on both the
capital owne dby its shareholders an dthe capital supplie dby lenders


Recognizing Success 129

on a long-term (over one year) basis. A business may borrow capital
rather than issue equity if it needs capital an dbelieves it will gen-
erate greater returns on the capital than the costs of borrowing it.
Suppose a business with $100 million in shareholder equity bor-
rows $50 million from long-term lenders an dthen generates earn-
ings of $15 million on that total capital. Its return on investment will
be 10% (15/150). But this leveraging boosts the business’s return on
equity—earnings of $15 million on shareholder equity of $100 mil-
lion means a return on equity of 15%.
Using debt to boost return on equity is common but by no means
imperative. Some companies generate sufficient cash from their op-
erations to enable high returns on equity more cheaply than they
coul dby borrowing. As was note dearlier, Microsoft is debt-free,
generating returns on equity of nearly 34% an dreturns on invest-
ment that are just about the same (a similar near 1:1 ratio holds
across the computer industry).
The norm among the S&P 500 is to use debt, driving the average
return on equity to about 22% while return on investment is about
14%. GE exploits leverage with more spectacular results, with returns
on equity of nearly 27% tripling return on investment of just above
9% (similar results hol dacross the conglomerate sector).

Return on Assets

Return on assets is the amount a business earns on all its re-
sources—not only shareholder equity an dlong-term borrowing but
short-term resources generate dby effective management of working
capital. A business may seek short-term, low-rate loans or buy goods
on credit that it resells for cash, thus increasing the assets available
for deployment at low or no cost. Those assets contribute to incre-
mental increases in earnings, boosting both return on equity an
return on assets.
Suppose a business maintains an average amount of short-term
assets of $20 million over a year (by continually repaying the obli-
gations as they come due an dincurring new ones as rollovers). That
coul dincrease incremental annual earnings by, say, $2 million. Thus,
a company with shareholder equity of $100 million an dlong-term
debt of $50 million, carrying that a itional $20 million in the short
term an dearning $17 million, generates a return on assets of 10%
(17/170). This deployment boosts return on investment to 11.3%
(17/150) an dreturn on equity to 17% (17/100).


130 Show Me the Money

Return on assets is thus the toughest measure of performance
base don returns, as it reveals the results of deploying all the assets
at management’s disposal. Starting with a high return on assets
shoul dyiel da high return on investment an dhence on equity. (Some
analysts calculate a “financial leverage index” equal to the return on
equity divide dby the return on assets.)
Higher returns on assets are achieve dby squeezing earnings out
of fewer or smaller asset bases. Microsoft starts off with a return on
assets of 25%, suggesting a relatively low level of asset intensity,
freeing it from dependency on debt an denabling it to generate re-
turns on equity of nearly 10 points more. At the other extreme, GE
starts off with a return on assets of just 3%, meaning it must manage
its capital structure to use debt skillfully an eploy assets efficiently
in order to get the higher returns on equity of about 27% that it
achieves.
Microsoft is asset-nonintensive, whereas GE is quite asset-
intensive. The earnings of many companies (Amazon.com maybe)
are driven by bran dnames and/or inventory an istribution systems
far more than by the plants an dother physical resources that make
up their balance sheet assets. Microsoft relies more on fixe dan
other assets but also is able to extract prodigious earnings from its
bran dname an dmarket position. GE’s asset-intensive business re-
quires heavy investment in plants an dequipment even as its prod-
ucts enjoy enormous bran drecognition (“We bring goo dthings to
life”).
It is too soon to tell how Amazon.com will fare in the contest
for high returns on assets. Certainly its business model is designe
to minimize asset intensity. Its bran dname an dInternet presence
are the key drivers of sales an dhence earnings. It minimizes its fixe
asset needs by avoiding the bricks-and-mortar store operations to
which Barnes & Noble an dother traditional retailers devote re-
sources.
Amazon.com’s just-in-time inventory management is designe dto
reduce the carrying costs of inventory. Its trade terms with customers
an dsuppliers drive incremental earnings by superior short-term
working capital management—it receives revenues from customers
as products are ordere dbut usually nee dnot pay its suppliers for
those goods until some 30 to 60 days later. Internet customers base
purchases on pictures an dimages on the Internet screen, moreover,
meaning Amazon.com does not suffer from books damage dby cus-
tomers thumbing through them. Bricks-and-mortar bookstores incur


Recognizing Success 131

losses from such damage dbooks (though they have the right to re-
turn damage dbooks to publishers, the result is often a lower dis-
count on purchases from them). These characteristics of low asset
intensity are extremely favorable to Amazon.com, though it remains
a har dbusiness to assess given its relative youth an dnegative earn-
ings.

THE FULL TOOL CHEST

This tool chest of ideas helps you assess a company’s liquidity, effi-
ciency, an dperformance. The tools can be adapte dfrom the basic
metrics outline dhere to deal with special situations an dmore ad-
vance danalysis.
A few examples of measures that help further gauge various as-
pects of a company’s relative an dprobable future success are as
follows. Quality of income (cash flows provide dby operating activi-
ties divide dby operating income) tells you what portion of income
is actually turning into cash to gauge the liquidity position. The
amount of annual depreciation expense can be a goo dproxy for fu-
ture capital investment needs. Sales per employee helps evaluate
overall productivity.
A company’s key ratios vary with time, an dany trends are im-
portant guides to managerial efficiency an dperformance. Therefore,
you might look at all the expenses on the income statement over
several years. There is no reason to automatically assume that any
particular ratio or trends will continue, but history does help define
probabilities for the future.
Suppose, for example, you see a large reduction in an expense
for research an evelopment. That woul dsignificantly increase in-
come in a period. But growth in income resulting from the reduction
in such an expense woul dnot mean that the business is being man-
age dmore efficiently. It coul deven mean that there are reasons to
worry about its prospects for growth in the future.
Or take receivables turns. Suppose the average number of col-
lection days during a perio dincreases materially in relation to the
credit terms. Maybe part of any sales growth during the perio dis
due to a relaxation in credit collection policies rather than to busi-
ness efficiency. If those accounts are more likely to go uncollected,
the sales growth might look goo dtoday but there’ll be hell to pay
tomorrow.


132 Show Me the Money

We coul dgo on an don but don’t nee dto.3 Get acquainte dwith
the key ratios mentione dabove an dyou’ll instantly be miles ahea
of the crow din your ability to distinguish strengths an dweaknesses
in numerous businesses within your circle of competence. Focus on
the strong ones an dkeep looking—they might have the value you
want, especially if they pass the tests in the next chapter.


C h a p t e r 9

YOU MAKE THE CALL

business is worth the present value of the future cash flows it
Agenerates from now until doomsday. Present value is in the eye
of the beholder, for its realization is entirely in the future. People
will disagree at virtually every step of the process of figuring present
value, including the methods use dan dthe different answers they
yield.
Gazing into the cloudy crystal ball of valuation, you can never
be sure of the accuracy of forecasts when you make them. Yet since
your future wealth is at stake, you do not want to fly blindfolde
even if you cannot predict the future. What you can do is minimize
the hazards of your errors.
What drives cash flows are assets an dearnings. These factors
an dhistorical cash flows are the best gauges for thinking about prob-
able future cash flows. You coul dfigure value base djust on assets
(something calle dbook value), base djust on earnings (what the
earnings stream is worth), or from the cash flows (the worth of the
dividends pai dout to shareholders).
However, none of these separate valuation tools in itself is usu-
ally sufficient to determine the value of a business. Not only is none
of them definitive, all of them together remain imperfect, for all
share the inevitable an dirremovable infirmity in any valuation ex-
ercise: using current an dpast information to forecast future cash
flows. You’ll nee dinformation about all these things to ai dyour judg-
ment.
Some valuation tools are more useful for certain businesses than
for others. For example, GE generates earnings an dpays cash divi-
dends, Microsoft generates earnings but does not pay cash dividends,
an dAmazon.com does neither. Obviously, you can value all three
companies by using asset measures; you can value GE an dMicrosoft
base don earnings, an dGE base don dividends.

133

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


134 Show Me the Money

Less obviously, you coul duse all these tools—but in different
ways—for all three companies. That is, estimate dfuture earnings
an ividends can be made for all three (relatively easy for GE, less
so for Microsoft, an dvery har dfor Amazon.com).
If these companies are within your circle of competence, you
can do it. You can do it even if you are nervous about using the huge
number of valuation techniques that are discusse din innumerable
books or below because none of them will enable you or anyone else
to pinpoint with precision what the value of any business is.
At best, these techniques produce a range of values that depen
on your interpretation of history an dprognosis for the future. These
acts expose you an deveryone else to risks of error, an dthose risks
are precisely why Ben Graham insiste don getting a thick margin of
safety between the price pai dan dthe value one coul dreasonably
expect to get. Every star investor follows that principle.
In the most famous chapter of The Intelligent Investor, Graham
wrote: “In the ol dlegen dthe wise men finally boile own the his-
tory of mortal affairs into the single phrase, ‘This too will pass.’ Con-
fronte dwith a like challenge to distill the secret of soun dinvesting
into three words, we venture the motto, MARGIN OF SAFETY.”1
Commenting on this passage over 40 years later, Warren Buffett sai
he still believes those are the right three words.2
Getting a wide gap between the price you pay an dthe value you
buy is the cornerstone of intelligent investing because as Buffett
says, while “intrinsic value can be define dsimply,” its calculation
“is not so simple.”3 Graham invoke dthe margin of safety principle
to avoi dthe risk of error in calculating intrinsic value. An dwhile
Charlie Munger—Buffett’s business partner an dalter ego—has
quippe dthat he has never seen Buffett do an intrinsic value calcu-
lation, the principles that follow are part of the mind-set that enables
him not to.

ASSETS

The book value of a company is the excess of its total assets as
set forth on the balance sheet over its total liabilities an dany out-
standing preferre dstock, also as set forth on the balance sheet. The
book value per share of a common stock of that business is simply
that amount divide dby the number of common shares outstand-
ing.


You Make the Call 135

This use of the wor d“value” is misleading. Balance sheets list
assets at their cost when acquire drather than their current value
(or in some cases at current market values if lower). The balance
sheet report of the carrying amount of assets does not reflect in-
creases in value under current market conditions. An dwhile the
long-term assets are shown less the depreciation on them, that is
only an approximation of what it woul dcost to replace them rather
than an exact figure.
The range of book values per share is as broa das the range of
businesses itself, an dall those values reflect historical acquisition
costs rather than current values. The book value per share of our
sample illustrates this. GE’s is about $12; Microsoft’s, about $6; an
Amazon.com’s, about $2.4
These numbers correctly suggest that the usefulness of book
value decays when more productive activity is performe dwith fewer
rather than more tangible assets (as more production is generate
not by, say, steel mills an dother factories but by information tech-
nologies an dInternet distribution systems). The fact that GE’s book
value per share is six times Amazon.com’s may reflect more the
greater asset intensity of GE’s business compare dto Amazon.com’s
than the value of those businesses.
For a whole range of businesses, the current accounting system
base don historical cost is handicappe din appraising present an
future values. For example, GE’s property, plant, an dequipment if
sol dat current market prices woul dfetch a substantial multiple of
the book value per share; Amazon.com’s might fetch only about what
the book value says, chiefly because all its assets were acquire
within the past few years.
Not only does this cost principle mean that some assets liste
on a balance sheet are worth far more than their liste damount, it
also means that the opposite is true. Even if book value purports to
reflect the amount for which a company coul dbe sol d(its liquida-
tion value), it cannot reflect the circumstances under which a sale
is held. A business liquidation conducte dunder or cause dby adverse
conditions may lea dto assets such as inventory an dequipment an
machinery being sol dat a loss compare dto their balance sheet carry-
ing amounts.
For some companies, losses on major assets such as plants an
warehouses can be enormous. If Disney were liquidated, for exam-
ple, there is reason to doubt that its theme park fixe dassets—an
important part of its book value—coul dbe sol dat their book value.


136 Show Me the Money

Perhaps more obviously, if Coke were liquidated, its inventory of
syrup an dconcentrate woul dundoubtedly fetch far less in a fire sale
of those goods than the amount at which they are carrie das inven-
tory on its balance sheet.
This does not mean that the balance sheet is useless. It is a
starting point for analysis. All the historical numbers can be adjuste
to reflect prevailing economic conditions. On the upside, inflation
an dappreciation in market values can be acknowledge dto arrive at
a current measure of the financial value of assets. Guides to this
adjusting of ol dnumbers to new conditions include sales prices of
similar property an dincreasing asset amounts base don changes in
the consumer price index.
On the downside, the historical amount of assets recorde don a
balance sheet can be reduce dto the amount they coul dbe sol dfor
in a fire sale upon liquidation of the business. How much to reduce
the amounts for things such as inventory an daccounts receivable
woul epen don their respective turnover rates. Amazon.com’s in-
ventory, for example, turns so quickly (24 times a year) that even in
a fire sale the company woul dprobably be able to get ri dof it at
pretty close to cost (the amount liste don its balance sheet). Some
of GE’s inventory, which turns only eight times per year, might have
to be sol dat a loss.
Even those adjustments may not serve as an accurate basis for
financial valuation, however, because of another accounting princi-
ple: the principle of economic or monetary exchange. A business
enterprise may have financial value derive dfrom intangible assets
that are not recorde din the financial statements because they were
not attributable to any discrete economic exchange. For example,
only the cost of development of intellectual property (such as pat-
ents, trademarks, an dcopyrights) is recorde das an asset on the bal-
ance sheet even if the property is worth billions of dollars in the
form of bran drecognition or customer loyalty.
You undoubtedly recognize the GE bran dname, for instance,
an dcollective consumer recognition is certainly valuable, but you
will not see any line item for GE’s bran dnames an dassociate din-
tellectual property on its balance sheet. The same is true for com-
pany know-how, employee capital an deducation, an dsimilar items
increasingly crucial to many companies in a wide variety of busi-
nesses, particularly but not exclusively companies such as Microsoft
an dAmazon.com.
These sources of value are referre dto as economic goodwill, a


You Make the Call 137

bundle of intangible assets that enable a business to generate su-
perior returns on equity, investment, an dassets. They can, as was
note dbefore, create a franchise or branding power that enables a
business to increase prices without hurting total sales volume. Dis-
ney, for example, can raise ticket prices to Disneylan dwithout hurt-
ing attendance.
Another sort of goodwill is calle daccounting goodwill. This is a
recor dof prices pai dfor businesses a company acquire dat a pre-
mium to book value. The economic value of accounting goodwill is
even trickier to appraise. If the purchase was a prudent one, the
value of the economic goodwill obtaine dis usually greater than the
amount of accounting goodwill. That is especially true because an-
other accounting rule requires that accounting goodwill be amor-
tized—reduce dannually by specifie damounts over future decades.
But again, if the businesses were smartly bought, the goodwill value
shoul drise over those years rather than, as the amortization sug-
gests, fall.
Sidestepping the nee dfor these adjustments to the balance
sheet, an old-fashione drule of thumb champione dby Ben Graham
says that a common stock carries a sufficient margin of safety if it
can be bought at a price equivalent to less than the company’s net
current assets,5 that is, a price equal to per share working capital.
This means that the buyer woul dpay nothing for the business’s fixe
assets. Such companies are so rare today that this tool in its pristine
form is of little use.
But a modest variation retains the ol drule’s conservative rigor
while still catching some fish. A business still qualifies if it can be
bought for its net current assets plus, say, half the original cost of its
fixe dassets. Thus, the investor pays for net working capital at the
state dvalue an dgets a 50% discount for all the other assets. In the
case of most companies today this woul dstill be quite a low figure, but
some companies—particularly smaller ones—en dup in your nets.6
The potential trouble with these approaches is that they relegate
you to being a bottom fisher—the person trolling for very low price
businesses. That is fine, but you nee dto be careful not to buy a
dying fish. Bargain hunting leads to disaster if all you get is a burst
of economic return but nothing in the long term. Prudent investors
hunt for stocks with fair rather than cheap prices an dstrong rather
than modest economic characteristics. As Warren Buffett advises, it
is better to buy a great business at a fair price than a fair business
at a great price.


138 Show Me the Money

A neophyte investor’s mistake, in any event, is to assess business
value solely on the basis of the balance sheet, even after overcoming
the limits impose dby accounting principles. Unless you are indee
valuing a company for purposes of liquidating it, what you really
want to know is not what its assets coul dsell for but what earnings
an dcash they spin off.
Graham recognize dthe limits of a balance sheet. Noting that it
is quite useful with respect to working capital position, Graham cau-
tione dthat it is of less use concerning the carrying amount of fixe
assets, which he sai d“must not be taken too seriously,” an dthe
figure at which intangible assets are listed, to which he sai d“little
if any weight shoul dbe given.”7 He advised:

It is true that in many individual cases we fin dcompanies with
small asset values earning large profits, while others with large
asset values earn little or nothing. Yet in these cases some at-
tention must be given to the book value situation, for there is
always a possibility that large earnings on the investe dcapital
may attract competition an dthus prove temporary; also that
large assets, not now earning profits, may later be made more
productive.8

Accordingly, Graham conclude dthat “book value is of some im-
portance in analysis because a very rough relationship tends to exist
between the amount investe din a business an dits average earnings,”
where the real money is.9

EARNINGS

Earnings refer to accounting earnings as reporte don the “bottom
line” of an income statement. These figures are separate dinto basic
earnings per share an ilute dearnings per share. Basic earnings
per share are the total earnings divide dby the average number of
common shares outstanding during the period.
Dilute dearnings take account of the possibility that some con-
vertible securities an dstock options coul dincrease the number of
common shares outstanding. This reduces the earnings per share by
taking into account the conversion or exercise of those instruments.
Focus on the dilute dearnings per share (an dbear in min dthat even
that figure does not always reflect full dilution or cost of stock op-
tions issue dto managers, as we will see later).

You Make the Call 139

In assessing what the enterprise can do for you in the future,
you only have present an dpast earnings available. How can present
an dpast earnings guide an assessment of future earnings? Or which
of various prior year earnings or which combination is the “right”
level of earnings?
In GE’s case, four recent annual dilute dearnings per share were
$2.16, $2.46, $2.80, an d$3.22; in Amazon.com’s, negative $.06,
.$24, $.84, an d$2.18 per share.
Perhaps you shoul duse only the most recent period. But what
if, as with GE an dAmazon.com, there is significant change in that
year compare dto the prior years? One issue is, of course, why that
change occurred. Was it due to extraordinary factors that are unlikely
to recur?
If that is the case, using the prior periods might seem appropri-
ate, though a more precise gauge for companies that periodically
experience such extraordinary occurrences is to lengthen the perio
to seven to ten years to iron out those bumps. Alternatively, perhaps
the business is experiencing a steady positive or negative tren din its
earnings. In these cases, averaging the earnings over the last four
years makes sense. In GE’s case, that is about $2.66 (in Ama-
zon.com’s, negative $.83).
All these issues obviously entail judgment, an don top of that
you must recognize that the estimate is about future earnings. Tak-
ing the average earnings over the past four years an dprojecting them
forwar dto the next four years requires a further forecast of the earn-
ings growth in the future period. Despite steadily rising losses, Am-
azon.com’s management expects profits within a few years (as
apparently do thousands of its stockholders, who at one point in the
early 2000s drove its market capitalization to over ten times the
combine dtotals of its profit-making archrivals Borders an dBarnes
& Noble!).
GE’s earnings growth rate was about 12 to 15% in the late 1990s.
You might cautiously expect similar or slightly slower growth in the
early 2000s. Taking a conservative view of the future coul djustify a
10% growth rate—roughly $3.50, $3.90, $4.30, an d$4.75, or an
average of about $4.10.
In estimating earnings, note again the limits of accounting rec-
ords. Accounting earnings result from subtracting cash expenses
plus noncash expenses such as depreciation an dba ebt reserves
from gross revenue. This sounds simple, but the exercise entails
making a number of decisions about how various events are ac-


140 Show Me the Money

counte dfor. Accounting earnings are affecte dby a host of account-
ing conventions, including, for example, the metho dof computing
the cost of goods sold, the metho dof depreciating fixe dassets, an
policies concerning allowance for ba ebts.
But imperfect accounting rules are still effective. With respect
to earnings (as distinguishe dfrom, say, book value), accounting rules
work when properly an dconsistently applied. Even if depreciation
expense for fixe dassets such as computers is not a perfect gauge of
the future costs of replacing them when they wear out, for example,
it does capture a minimum reasonable amount that must be rein-
veste din the business to maintain its sales level an dcompetitive
position in the future.
Once a representative earnings figure is selected, the earnings
must be discounted. Doing this requires a suitable discount rate
(conventionally calle dthe capitalization rate or cap rate). It is the
rate of return require dto compensate for the risk of making the
investment, an dso it is equal to the risk-free rate (that available on
U.S. Treasury obligations) plus an a itional amount to reflect the
particular risk of the business.
Assume you determine that GE’s expecte dearnings over the next
four will be about $4.10 per share. The price you are willing to pay
for the right to that $4.10 per share in the future is a function of
the rate of return necessary to compensate for the risk that the $4.10
per year will not materialize. It will equal the risk-free rate—say,
3%—plus a premium to induce you to take the risk of owning GE
stock.
A robust debate centers on what the right cap rates are for dif-
ferent businesses an dtypes of investments. In general, the lower the
risks involve din a particular type of business, the lower the cap rate.
For example, if there is a high degree of certainty that a business
will continue to perform as it has in the past, a cap rate in the range
of aroun d10% is appropriate. For businesses that present moderate
degrees of risk, a cap rate in the range of 15 to 25% is better. For
particularly risky businesses, those where uncertainty about future
success is great, an appropriate cap rate coul drange from 30 to 40%
up to 100%.
Businesses whose earnings fluctuate widely in the ordinary
course may be seen as subject to a greater risk that estimate dearn-
ings will vary. For example, banks an dinsurance companies whose
assets consist largely of cash or investments are more expose dto
cycles of economic change an dmay warrant a discount rate in the


You Make the Call 141

range of 8 to 12%. Consumer products businesses—those selling
foods an etergents, for example—ten dto remain more stable dur-
ing periods of both boom an dbust an dthus generally warrant a
lower-risk cap rate in the range of, say, 6 to 8%.
In a ition to depending on the risk-free rate of interest, an
appropriate cap rate takes into account the rate of economic growth
in the overall economy. During periods of steady economic growth
an dindustry expansion, risks are relatively lower. During economic
downturns, growth is less likely, even steady earnings are less likely,
an dthere is a greater likelihoo dof overall earnings contractions. In
such an environment, risk rises, an dyou shoul dchoose higher cap
rates.
Therefore, the rules of thumb for cap rates have to be set ac-
cording to the risk-free rate, the risks of a particular business, an
those of industry in general. Equally important, we must adjust the
cap rate to allow for future variations. If interest rates rise or the
economy slows, for example, the cap rate will have to be increased,
an dvice versa.
The difficulties in estimating earnings an dselecting a cap rate
relate back to your circle of competence. Just as an appreciation of
economic history is essential, knowledge of the operating context is
indispensable for the forecasting exercise. GE, Microsoft, an dAm-
azon.com all look exceptionally well managed, with Amazon.com
even scoring some knockout points in the key ratios, though GE an
Microsoft also make money from goo dmanagement.
GE is a money machine, particularly in its capital financing di-
vision. It delivere dsteady earnings increases throughout nearly all
its 100 years an devery year during the last 20. Its diverse businesses
an dleadership in virtually all of them suggest a reasonable basis for
forecasting continue dsteady earnings generation in the future,
though that is never free from doubt because of evolving economic
environments. With GE’s distinguishe dperformance, however, a
modest cap rate is perfectly reasonable.
Let’s assume GE warrants a risk premium just above the risk-
free rate—say, 5%—an dapply it to our estimate of average future
earnings of about $4.10. An estimate of GE’s value can be made
simply by dividing the earnings estimate by the cap rate, in other
words, $4.10 divide dby .05, which equals $82 per share.
If we took a slightly more aggressive guess about GE’s earnings
prospects, our valuation woul dlook different. Suppose, for example,
we forecast the earnings at $5.00. Still using the cap rate of 5%


142 Show Me the Money

woul dgive us a value per GE share of $100 (5.00/.05). If you go
further an eem a lower cap rate of, say, 4% more appropriate given
GE’s prowess an dcurrent business opportunities an dconditions, the
value per share shoots up to $125 (5.00/.04).
This play with the numbers gives a valuation for GE with a fairly
wide range of $82 to $125. The range is broader yet if we take a
more pessimistic view. If you use only the average earnings of the
past four years of $2.66 an dstick with our original discount rate of
5%, the valuation is about $53. If you believe the roa dahea dis
riskier than the roa djust travele dso that a cap rate of, say, 6% is
more suitable, the value becomes $44 per share, generating a “Texas
range” from $44 to $125.
The selection of your earnings estimate an iscount rate is cru-
cial to this exercise. (A plausible range of values for Amazon.com,
for example, starts from zero an dgoes to a few hundre ollars!)
But even if you make those selections ruthlessly, your result cannot
be the “answer” to the question of what a share of such stock is
“worth.” After all, there are plenty of steps in the process where your
judgment coul dturn out to be wrong.

SILVER BULLETS AND THE MARGIN OF SAFET

Most people agree that discount rates are driven by the risk-free rate
of interest in effect from time to time, usually that available on U.S.
government bonds that are deeme dfree of any default risk. This
coul drange from the prevailing rate of about 3%, to the historical
average of about 3.5%, to the present rate on inflation-protecte
government bonds of about 4%. Some people use bonds of shorter
durations (such as 30 days instea dof 30 years), but since equities
are inherently long term (i.e., corporations have perpetual duration),
it is probably better to use the long bond.
After settling on a risk-free rate, you then a a premium for
your stock. The tendency is to look at the average rates of return on
equities overall for long periods of time, which has been roughly 7%.
That gives you an average risk premium of 3 to 3.5%, which must
be tailore dto the individual stock you are investigating. The rules
of thumb mentione dabove get you a long way here, though you
shoul dknow that many try to be very precise about these matters.


You Make the Call 143

Believers in the modern finance stories discusse dearlier, for exam-
ple, multiply the market risk premium by a stock’s ? to come up with
an appropriate discount rate.
All this disagreement an dthe examples we’ve just gone through
show you that there is plenty of play in the valuation enterprise. Tiny
variations in your assumptions take the bottom line in widely differ-
ent directions an dmagnitudes. A 1% change in your guess about the
market premium, for example, throws off an appropriate level for the
S&P Index by about 200 points (an dmore if you also play aroun
with your estimate of future earnings growth rates).
Your best approach remains artistic judgment rather than sci-
entific precision. Phil Carret made it one of his investing command-
ments to “ignore mechanical formulas for valuing securities.”10 Sorry
to disappoint you if you expecte dmagical solutions an dthink you
haven’t gotten them. In a sense, though, magic is what you get.
Graham delivere dthe silver bullet of investing when he sai dthe
three most important words in investing philosophy are “margin of
safety.” Recognizing that it is essentially impossible to pinpoint the
precise intrinsic value of a business an dthat the best you can do is
compute reasonable ranges of value base don reasonable assump-
tions, Graham thought you shoul dgive yourself a break by making
sure the price you pay is way lower than the low en dof your valu-
ation estimate.
Graham calle dthe margin of safety the central concept of in-
vestment because its essential function is to render an accurate es-
timate of the future unnecessary. In using it, you nee dnot stress or
struggle over the precise way to define the “right” risk premium,
earnings, or discount rate so long as you have a reasonable approx-
imation of what makes sense. Its secondary function is to absorb the
effect of error in your assumptions—an dremember, even tiny errors
cause huge effects—as well as the effect of plain ba dluck.
Graham observe dthat most investing errors are made not so
much by paying too high a price for high-quality stocks as by buying
low-quality stocks during times of economic prosperity (much as in
early 2000s America). Indeed, Graham repudiate da strategy that
overemphasizes what the fashion plates of finance call growth stocks.
If you can get the same margin of safety by carefully estimating the
future of growth stocks, more power to you, but the danger is that
growth stocks ten dto be favorites an dfavoritism in stocks is mea-
sure dby high prices that steal safety margins.11


144 Show Me the Money

Graham sai dthe margin of safety principle ultimately serve das
the touchstone in distinguishing between investing an dspeculation.
Those who deny the difference between price an dvalue or fail to
get a margin of safety take their seats at the roulette wheel. Place
your bets!

CASH

The same judgment can be applie dto the cash a company is ex-
pecte dto generate an dpay to shareholders in the future. The cash
dividend–base dapproach to valuation was champione dby John Burr
Williams, who argue das follows:

Earnings are only a means to an end, an dthe means shoul dnot
be mistaken for the end. Therefore we must say that a stock
derives its value from its dividends, not its earnings. In short, a
stock is worth only what you can get out of it.
In saying that dividends, not earnings, determine value, we
seem to be reversing the usual rule that is drille dinto every
beginner’s hea dwhen he [or she] starts to trade in the market;
namely, that earnings, not dividends, make prices. The apparent
contradiction is easily explained, however, for we are discussing
permanent investment, not speculative trading, an ividends
for years to come, not income for the moment only.
Of course it is true that low earnings together with a high
dividen dfor the time being shoul dbe looke dat askance, but
likewise it is true that these low earnings mean low dividends in
the long run. On analysis, therefore, it will be seen that no con-
tradiction really exists between our formula using dividends an
the common precept regarding earnings.12

Williams indicates that dividen iscounting an dearnings capi-
talization give the same answer (or range of answers) to the question
of what a share of stock is worth.
This is the case because dividends are a subset of earnings. A
corporation can deploy its earnings either by paying them out to
shareholders as dividends or retaining them for reinvestment in the
business. If the retaine dearnings generate a return equal to the cap
rate, the value you get from capitalizing the earnings stream will be
the same as the value you get from discounting the dividen dstream.
Indeed, valuation by discounting dividends is analytically iden-


You Make the Call 145

tical to the capitalization of earnings technique. An assume ivi-
den dpayment is divide dby an assume iscount rate, just as an
assume dearnings level was divide dby an assume dcap rate. In each
case, the questions are (1) What does the expecte dstream look like
in terms of amount an dgrowth? an d(2) What is the risk that the
amount an dgrowth will not be realized?
The conceptual difference between the two techniques is that in
discounting dividends you assume that the value of a share of stock
is the present value of the expecte ividen dpayments on it from
now until doomsday. This makes sense because the value of the stock
consists of the payment stream it yields while it is owne dan dwhen
it is sold.
The only reason there will be a gain on sale is that some other
investor wants to buy the payment stream, an dso on. These inves-
tors may or may not be correct or even rational in that determi-
nation, but it is precisely differences in valuation judgments that
lea dto such exchanges anyway. As a result, the value of a share of
common stock resides solely in its expecte dstream of cash divi-
dends.
Discounting dividends is just as difficult as capitalizing earnings
because both require selecting a highly sensitive discount rate. For
dividen iscounting, many people try to minimize this difficulty by
using the subject’s weighte daverage cost of capital. But that is not
a uniquely correct number, an dcalculating it requires just as much
judgment as they are trying to escape.
Calculating the weighte daverage cost of a company’s indebted-
ness is relatively easy: It is the average interest rate on all long-term
obligations weighte daccording to the various amounts of principal
outstanding on each type of debt. Figuring out the cost of a com-
pany’s equity capital is far harder.
The cost of equity is usually define dby what the market expects
the annualize dreturn on the stock to be, combining price appreci-
ation an ividen dpayout. But what are we really doing here? In
determining a stock’s value, we are trying to figure out what the
return is going to be. If your key variable in that figuring is what the
market expects, you are begging the question. You are assuming the
answer rather than analyzing the question.
You are better off forming your own value judgment. There is no
formula to tell you the answer, as these examples emphasize. Your
only frien dat that point is the Graham-Buffett margin of safety, not
Mr. Market (you may be fallible; we know Mr. Market is).


146 Show Me the Money

MARKET CIRCULARIT

The greatest deficiency in using market metrics for valuation is the
problem of circularity. To say that a share of Exxon-Mobil is “worth”
what the stock last trade dfor tells you nothing about how that last
trade was valued. Of course we know how it was priced: by the forces
of supply an eman din the stock market. We also know from Part
I that those forces are far from rational; are infecte dby emotion,
psychology, an dnoise; an dmay even be chaotic.
But that is all we know. None of this tells you whether the price
is a product of analysis or hope or fear, is a product of discounting
expecte dfuture earnings or cash flows, or is base don a determine
multiple of book values or on hunches an dguesses.
You can try to penetrate the problem of market circularity by re-
membering John Burr Williams’s point that the value of any asset is the
amount of cash flow it will generate in the future, discounte dby the
probability that those flows will materialize. You coul dargue that a col-
lection of comparable assets yields a particular return an duse that
comparable return as the discounting factor. But not only are you left
with the challenge of defining comparable assets, you still have not de-
termine dthe basis on which those comparable assets have been value
(other than, again circularly, by the market’s collective judgment).
Countless books an darticles have been written about how in-
terest rates an dother returns are determine dby the market, but no
one knows for sure. Interest rates vary according to people’s collec-
tive inclination to borrow for immediate consumption or invest for
future consumption (say, at retirement). These inclinations are
shape dnot only by roughly quantifiable conditions such as produc-
tivity an dreturns an dthe supply of money but by behavioral an
psychological conditions that are virtually impossible to measure an
in any event are highly unstable.
People undoubtedly have specific expectations about returns
from assets, but those expectations vary widely. Current survey data
show that people who live uring or in the aftermath of the Great
Depression now expect average annual returns on stock portfolios
that are in line with their averages in the postwar perio dof close to
10% while younger people with only history lessons rather than per-
sonal memories of that perio dexpect returns in line with those of
the 1990s of closer to 20%. (A similar gap has existe din other pe-
riods, such as the late 1960s.)13


You Make the Call 147

Neither of these groups is correct, for it is logically impossible
to say that any person is correct about the future. But these sorts of
expectations—founde din the infinitely complex map of human psy-
chology an dexperience—furnish the underpinnings of the returns
the market generates. Great expectations are inherently unreliable,
an dthe circularity of market metrics remains impenetrable.
Once you have made the call about value, you have to go to Mr.
Market to see what prices he is offering. While there, compare your es-
timation of value to a few price ratios before making a final decision.
There is no guarantee that stocks with low price ratios offer value
higher than their price, but they are a goo dplace to look. Nor do
high price ratios automatically mean a stock is unattractive, since
price still may be lower than value.14 Businesses with attractive op-
erating climates, liquidity an dperformance measures, an dearnings
records deserve a close look, particularly but not exclusively if all
the price ratios are low an dthe return on equity is high.

Price/Book Ratio

The relationship between a company’s stock market price an dits
book value is calle dthe price/book ratio (P/B ratio). It is equal to the
market price per share divide dby book value per share.
Comparing the P/B ratio of one business with its peers is a way
to gauge how investors regar dthat business compare dto others or
the industry average. Higher P/B ratios mean that investors regar
the stock more favorably.
The average P/B ratio for publicly trade dstock in the early 2000s
is aroun d2 to 3.5, with older, industrial companies (such as steel
companies) sometimes trading at P/B ratios near or below 1 an dnewer,
technology-oriente dcompanies (such as computer software manufac-
turers) sometimes trading at P/B ratios as high as 20 or more.
In our crop, Amazon.com’s P/B ratio leads the league at above
40, with Microsoft at about 15 an dGE at 10. While none of these
fits the bill, if you fin da stock trading below a P/B ratio of 1, you
can buy that stock for a price below the company’s net worth. Such
stocks are rare an dcertainly warrant further investigation.

Price/Sales Ratio

For most companies, a strong relationship between a company’s
value an dits sales levels shoul dexist. Sales drive growth. More sales


148 Show Me the Money

mean more earnings. A company cannot grow faster than its sales,
but it can grow more slowly with poor management, which will be
reflecte din poor efficiency an dperformance ratios.
The sales figure is also less affecte dby accounting conventions.
Since it is the top-line number on the income statement, pretty
much the only accounting rules affecting sales relate to the timing
of their recognition. While that can be manipulate dto an extent (this
is discusse dfurther in Chapter 10), it is far purer than the bottom-
line earnings number, which can be affecte dby scores of accounting
conventions.
Calculate the price/sales ratio (P/S ratio) by dividing the stock
price by the sales per share (this is not commonly reporte din finan-
cial statements but is an easy calculation to make). Alternatively, you
can follow the conventional but equivalent metho dof dividing the
total market capitalization (price times shares outstanding) by the
total sales. Either way, if you can buy a stock for a price that is equal
to or less than the company’s sales, you are on your way to getting
a goo dmargin of safety.
In our group, Microsoft is richly price dcompare dto its sales at
a P/S ratio of about 20, with Amazon.com also heftily price dat about
15, an dGE at about 5. No bargains exist on these numbers, but
again, if you can fin da company with a low P/S ratio, particularly
one that also has high profit margins, you are getting goo dvalue for
money.

Price/Earnings Ratio

Investors commonly use market prices to compare businesses by re-
lating trading prices to earnings per share. This is calle dthe price-
earnings ratio (P/E ratio), an dit is compute dby dividing the market
price of a share of common stock by the company’s earnings per
share. The limitations of using the earnings multiple for valuation
an dthe ruthlessness require dto specify a cap rate explain the pop-
ularity of P/E ratios as guides for selection.
In general, higher P/E ratios suggest that investors are more op-
timistic about a company’s prospects than they are about comparable
businesses with lower P/E ratios. The historical breakpoint for high
an dlow P/E ratios has been 15—above that was high, an dbelow it
was low. Very high P/E ratios (anything above 50) imply loads of
optimistic investors swooning over a company’s prospects. However,
the relative levels of P/E ratios also vary with a company’s growth out-


You Make the Call 149

look, industry, relative maturation (rookie, vintage, or classic), an
accounting policies use din calculating net income. Don’t count on
P/E ratios being comparable across companies.
The P/E ratios of our group of companies fluctuate dwildly dur-
ing the 1990s an dearly 2000s, along with the volatile overall market.
But suppose the market price of a share of common stock sits be-
tween 25 an d50 an dsuppose its average earnings per share are
aroun d$1.00. The P/E ratio thus has range dfrom 25 to 50. The
implied cap rate hovers between 2% an d4%. Does that mean you
shoul duse such rates? Why woul dit? But suppose a stock ha da P/E
ratio of 5. Now that sounds like a deal with a thick margin of safety.

Economic Value Added

Consider an all-industry metric create d(an dtrademarked!) by a
business consulting firm that apparently has realize dthat the mar-
ketplace is thirsting for new tools to justify all kinds of crazy ideas.15
The tool has been cleverly name d“economic value a ed” (EVA). It
says that a company’s performance can be evaluate din terms of
whether returns on capital are higher than costs of capital. If they
are, value is being a ed.
Though the components of the EVA calculation are simple to
state—the company’s return on capital minus its weighte daverage
cost of capital—we already know that pinning down the latter is a
lot harder than it sounds.
For EVA, the weighte daverage cost of capital coul dbe define
simply as the appropriate discount rate at which to value the com-
pany, but that doesn’t escape the circularity trap. Or it coul dbe the
cost of the company’s indebtedness—the average interest rate pai
on its debt during the measure dperiod. But if that is all it is, then
EVA is just another name for leverage.
If it includes a mixe dmeasure of the cost of debt an dthe ex-
pecte dreturn on equity, the measure not only still has the problem
of circularity but also gets nonparsimonious. All it really tells you is
by how much a company beat expectations. If return on equity last
year was 10% an dthe market this year expects the same 10% but the
company actually has delivere d12%, EVA says it increase dvalue by
an a itional 2%—but you don’t nee da name like EVA to tell you
that.
Worse, part of the motivation to develop tools such as EVA was
to overcome earnings management techniques: managerial manip-


150 Show Me the Money

ulation of revenue recognition timing, restructuring charges, an
others discusse din the next chapter. These techniques proliferate in
proportion to investor emphasis on (or obsession with) whether a
company meets analysts’ earnings expectations. EVA exacerbates
rather than solves the problem, because it applauds managers only
when they excee dexpectations.
Moreover, if EVA is intende dto measure a company’s ability to
generate profits for shareholders on the amount of their investe
capital, it potentially suffers from the same weaknesses of traditional
financial ratios: They all rely on the integrity of the underlying ac-
counting data use dto calculate profit. EVA tends to increase rather
than reduce pressure on managers to manipulate (or make up) num-
bers.
None of this denies the underlying insight of EVA: assessing
performance base don how much extra return is generate dfrom a
dollar of investment. Indeed, in evaluating managerial performance,
we shoul educt from reporte dresults a charge for the capital em-
ploye din producing them (something rarely done, especially in con-
nection with reports an drewards of stock options tie dto returns, a
subject discusse din Part III). For some companies—Coke under
Roberto Goizueta, for example—returns on capital are so impressive
that even with difficulties in pinning down the cost of capital, there
is no question that returns excee dcosts by impressive distances.16
Obsession with EVA puts a false premium on precision, just as
the tools of modern finance discusse dearlier do. Though he believes
in the basic idea underlying EVA, Warren Buffett often says he pre-
fers to be approximately right than precisely wrong. Speaking pub-
licly at the Berkshire Hathaway 2000 annual shareholders meeting,
Charlie Munger put it more epigrammatically with a characteristi-
cally unglove enunciation of EVA: “bullshit.”

Graham’s comments on market price an dbusiness value are
worth memorizing:

The accepte didea that a common stock shoul dsell at a certain
ratio to its current earnings must be considere dmore the result
of practical necessity than of logic. The market takes the tren
or future prospects into account by varying this ratio for differ-
ent types of companies. Common stocks of enterprises with only
slight possibilities of increasing profits ordinarily sell at a rather
low price-earnings ratio (less than 15 times their current earn-
ings); an dthe common stocks of companies with goo dprospects


You Make the Call 151

of increasing the earnings usually sell at high price-earnings ra-
tio (over 15 times the current earnings). . . .
When neither boom nor deep depression is affecting the
market, the judgment of the public on individual issues, as in-
dicate dby market prices, is usually quite good. If the market
price of some [stock] appears out of line with the facts an
figures available, it will often be foun dlater that the price is
discounting future developments not then apparent on the sur-
face. There is, however, a frequent tendency on the part of the
stock market to exaggerate the significance of changes in earn-
ings both in a favorable an dunfavorable direction. This is man-
ifest in the market as a whole in periods of both boom an
depression, an dit is also evidence din the case of individual
companies at other times.
At bottom the ability to buy [stocks] successfully is the abil-
ity to look ahea daccurately. Looking backward, however care-
fully, will not suffice, an dmay do more harm than good. Com-
mon stock selection is a difficult art—naturally, since it offers
large rewards for success. It requires a skillful mental balance
between the facts of the past an dthe possibilities of the future.17


C h a p t e r 1 0

MAKING (UP)
NUMBERS

ccounting shenanigans have plague dbookkeeping since it was
Ainvente dby Luca Pacioli in 1494, an dthere is no reason to ex-
pect that the next 500 years will stray from the historical pattern.
No amount of rule making—from accounting, auditing, or else-
where—can ensure the integrity of financial reporting. Rules cannot
eliminate managerial discretion, an dthere will always be the possi-
bility of imaginative, unorthodox, creative, an deven fraudulent fi-
nancial reporting.
Investors an dmanagers shoul dexpect it and, instea dof wishing
it away, take pains not to be its victims or accomplices. Just think
of the notorious accounting frauds of relatively recent memory—
from Leasco, National Student Marketing, an dPenn Central in the
late 1960s an dearly 1970s to Cendant, MicroStrategy, an dSunbeam
in the late 1990s an dearly 2000s. These frauds sting investors, an
managers who engage in them shoul dknow they will be caught,
punished, an dmade to pay (though investors will not profit in the
process).
The nonfraudulent cases are often the trickier to deal with. They
consist of a variety of smoothing techniques designe dto massage the
whole range of financial numbers, from the ratios discusse dprevi-
ously to income itself. Income smoothing, also known as earnings
management, exploits the flexibility of generally accepte daccounting
principles to classify transactions or allocate them by time perio dto
achieve favorable financial reporting.

PERENNIALS

SEC Chairman Arthur Levitt delivere da series of major speeches in
the late 1990s an dearly 2000s identifying several long-standing ac-

153

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


154 Show Me the Money

counting issues that are hallmarks of earnings management. These
techniques are as ol das accounting itself an dhave been use dto full
advantage (sometimes appropriately, often not) by managers over the
centuries. Yet the contemporary problems are heightened, according
to Levitt, by a managerial obsession with meeting consensus earn-
ings estimates formulate dby the increasingly influential profession
of investment analysis.
This dizzying obsession with “making numbers” is documente
by the accounting professors Davi dBurgstahler of the University of
Washington an dIlia Dichev of the University of Michigan.1 They
show that about one in ten managers facing small declines in earn-
ings manage to show earnings increases, an dthat about four in ten
facing negative earnings manage to report positive earnings! The ob-
session with “making numbers” leads managers to make them up.
Levitt single dout five issues of particular concern, giving each
a catchy phrase intended, one supposes, for both poetic an dmne-
monic value.

• Big bath. Big bath accounting is a particularly aggressive version
of earnings management that is sort of a financial face-lift. It
lumps major events adversely affecting income in current periods
to facilitate improve dfinancial appearances in succeeding periods.
It is particularly common in, but by no means limite dto, costs
occasione dby acquisitions, divestitures, reorganizations, an dother
extraordinary organic business changes. These transactions call for
numerous accounting judgments in regar dto both timing an dclas-
sification. Managers often expense as much of the potential cost
of a transaction at the time it is consummate das possible. It’s also
tempting to give current earnings a “big bath” in one year to create
a brighter-looking future when the year is so dismal anyway that
investors have written it off (this happens all the time, even at
otherwise reputable companies).
• Merger magic. This describes a subset of creative accounting in
acquisitions. If a business buys another business for a price higher
than the seller’s book value, the buyer in most cases must recor
an asset calle daccounting goodwill (discusse din the last chapter)
an damortize that account as an expense over future decades. That
reduces earnings over that period. To minimize the reduction, a
buyer’s manager can allocate some or a lot of that excess to other
things, most notoriously to in-progress research-and-development


Making (Up) Numbers 155

(R&D) costs. Accounting rules require such R&D costs to be ex-
pense dwhen incurre d(rather than amortized), an dso many buyers
allocate that excess as a one-time expense at the merger time even
when that allocation defies business reality.
• Cookie jar reserves. This entails the overestimation or underesti-
mation of things such as sales returns by publishers, probable loan
losses of lending institutions, an dwarranty obligations for manu-
facturers. The incorrect estimation enables managers to adjust an
smooth out earnings as actual earnings vary from expecte dearn-
ings perio dto period.
• It’s not material. The materiality principle requires the reporting
of items that are material an dallows the nonreporting of items
that are not. Materiality is not an absolute concept but entails
making judgments. A standar dlegal formulation for public cor-
porations under federal securities laws is whether an item woul
be important to an investor in making an investment decision
about a security (the accounting rule similarly asks whether it
woul dinfluence a reasonable person’s judgment). Judgments con-
cerning materiality are often guide dby rough rules of thumb. One
rule of thumb accountants an dauditors often use in determining
materiality is whether a particular item entails more than, say, a
5% impact on a company’s earnings. But applying such a simple
rule coul dlea dto excluding things that are meaningful to a user
of the financial statements in a qualitative sense.
• Wine before its time. This image of popping open a bottle of wine
before it matures reflects the premature recognition of revenue.
For instance, a toy manufacturer may tag goods in a warehouse as
“sold” even though they are not an dmay never be sold, or a dis-
tributor of cell phones may recor drevenue for merchandise that
it shippe dan dreceive dpayment for but that is subject to free
return by the buyer for a perio dof, say, 90 days.

To a ress these manipulations, the SEC calle dfor immediate
an dcoordinate daction, seeking nothing less than a fundamental
change in American corporate culture. Levitt articulate da multifac-
ete dprogram, beginning with instructing the SEC staff to scrutinize
financials for abuses of restructuring accounting an daccruals for
losses an dreserves. He aske dthe American Institute of Certifie
Public Accountants (AICPA) to clarify auditing rules concerning
purchase dR&D, large acquisition write-offs, an drevenue recogni-



156 Show Me the Money

tion. He also instructe dthe SEC staff to focus on materiality not
solely in quantitative terms but also in qualitative terms, reject the
notion that materiality can excuse minor errors, an dpromulgate new
standards on revenue recognition.
Levitt also calle don private standard-setting organizations to join
the cause, particularly asking the Financial Accounting Standards
Boar d(FASB) to reconsider the definition of liabilities under gen-
erally accepte daccounting principles. He encourage dthe Public
Oversight Boar dto review an dintensify its focus on the audit
committees of boards an drecruit more members with financial back-
grounds (as oppose dto legal, marketing an dpublic service back-
grounds). He envisione daudit committees meeting more often an
asking tougher questions—what he calle da “private sector re-
sponse.” He impanele da blue ribbon commission to report on ways
to enhance the audit committee’s role an dultimately calle dupon
management itself an dWall Street to revitalize integrity in financial
reporting by cooperating an dsupporting these initiatives.
This program emboldene dthe SEC to prosecute scores of en-
forcement actions against companies engage din earnings manage-
ment of the sort Levitt highlighted. The SEC adopte dtougher rules
governing audits, including a requirement that quarterly financial
statements be reviewe dby auditors, an dmateriality rules that ex-
pressly deal with qualitative an dquantitative dimensions.2
Audit committees must now review an dvouch for the accuracy
of financial statements, provide a report in proxy statements con-
cerning whether they signe doff on the financial statements, state
whether a written charter spells out the committee’s duties, an dsub-
mit any such charter to the SEC every three years. The stock ex-
changes adopte drules requiring liste dcompanies to disclose
whether members of the audit committee are independent of man-
agement an drequiring audit committee members to have a financial
background.3
Levitt’s ambitious crusade is ongoing, an dinvestors shoul dsup-
port those who carry it out. No amount of effort, however, can elim-
inate the inevitable flexibility that generally accepte daccounting
principles provide or the temptations or capitulations to which they
lead. It remains for the intelligent investor to monitor financial re-
porting with measure dskepticism an dstay alert to the possibility of
distortion. While the past is no guarantee of the future, it certainly
is prologue, an das early as 1936 Ben Graham lampoone dcorporate


Making (Up) Numbers 157

America for its abuses of financial reporting, as have many since,
most notably City University of New York accounting professor Abra-
ham Briloff.4

SATIRE

Graham satirically hypothesize da phantom US Steel Corporation
adopting “advance dbookkeeping methods” to report “phenomenally
enhanced” earnings without any cash outlays or changes in operat-
ing conditions or sales. To update that illustration of accounting
chicanery, consider how a phantom company might today achieve
the same results by using techniques like those Levitt denounces.
Its press release an daccompanying financial reports might look like
this:

E-America Dot.Com Announces Positive Earnings

E-America Dot.Com today announce dpositive earnings, stunning
Wall Street analysts whose consensus view estimate dcontinue dneg-
ative earnings for the start-up that went public last year. Its stock
price shot up 40% on the news. Though this response is usually re-
serve dfor companies that report negative earnings, we believe it is
justifie dfor the same sort of reasons—none.
Rather than taking any action to increase sales or improve its
products, marketing strategy, distribution channels, or customer ser-
vice, the earnings increase was due to improvements in the manner
in which the company’s economic activity is recorde din its books.
These new bookkeeping methods report profits of $50 per share in-
stea dof the $25 loss per share that otherwise woul dbe reported. The
accounting improvements consist of the following steps:

• Modifying revenue recognition policies
• Adjusting reserves an dtreatment of returns
• Recording the value of market share as an asset
• Recording the amount of cash we “burn” as an asset
• Reporting in a different currency
• Refining the concept of materiality

The Boar dof Directors of E-America Dot.Com, in collusion with
their auditors, reache dthe following conclusions in adopting this pro-


158 Show Me the Money

gram in a resolution unanimously approve dat its boar dmeeting this
week:
The Boar dof Directors an dits Independent Outside Auditors,
after careful study an dreview, determine dthat the accounting policies
an dpractices the company use dsince its recent initial public offering
ten months ago are outdate dan o not reflect the kin dof perfor-
mance managers of the company expect or predict.
The Boar dan dits Auditors, aide dan dabette dby a special audit
committee, determine dthat many other companies obtain a compet-
itive advantage in the capital markets by reporting accounting results
in terms of innovative, cutting-edge techniques an dthat the company
was penalize dfor failing to follow these best practices, referre dto as
the “New Accounting.”
Adopting the New Accounting will neutralize this disadvantage
an denable the company to increase its market capitalization without
the nee dfor disbursing cash or changing any of its operating activities.
The changes adopte dby the Board, with the attestation of its Audi-
tors, are as follows:

m o d i f y i n g r e ve n u e
r e c o g n i t i o n p o l i c i e s

Competitive conditions in our industry lea dus to give generous credit
terms to our customers. These include giving them the right to return
goods to us for a full refun dif they cannot resell them to the ultimate
consumer within 180 days. We formerly deferre drecognizing the
revenue in connection with such transactions until after that 180-
day perio dpasse don the grounds that no sale was complete until
then.
But this ol deconomy policy substantially reduce dthe amount of
reporte dsales reflecte don our income statement. The Boar ecide
to treat those transactions as sales right away, on the grounds that
our sales team put tireless effort into generating them an dshoul dget
credit. (We can make adjustments for returns later, but for now we
woul drather report the goo dnews in the short term an efer the
ba dnews for the long term.)
In particular, we will occasionally “park” inventory with our cus-
tomers, to whom we give unconditional return rights either orally or
in “side letters” kept separate from the sales documents. As a result
of this scheme, we will report much higher sales revenue an ramatic
increases in earnings. If adjustments must be made to smooth those
earnings, we will restate past earnings in subsequent quarterly reports


Making (Up) Numbers 159

an isclose that these resulte dfrom a problem with the “collectibil-
ity” of our accounts receivable.

a d j u s t i n g r e s e r ve s a n d
t r e a t m e n t o f r e t u r n s

In the financing arm of our business, we inten dto reduce the amount
of reserves we recor dfor delinquent an duncollectible accounts by
reporting them as current. To do so, we will in some cases simply
exten dthe due dates of our customers’ obligations. In others, we will
assume that we can repossess the items secure dby these delinquent
loans whether or not that is feasible. This enables us to recor dfar
lower reserves in our allowance for credit losses, thus increasing our
net income.
Similarly, in all of our businesses, we will recor dcustomers’ re-
turns of merchandise as purchases of goods rather than charging
them against our reserves for returns. Another benefit of this new
policy is to increase our receivable turns, making our operations look
speedier an dmore efficient.

r e c o r d i n g t h e va l u e o f
m a r k e t s h a r e a s a n a s s e t

A hot tren din the marketplace for traders an dspeculators is to assign
a value to Internet companies base don the percentage of their prod-
uct market their sales levels represent. This is necessary to justify the
stratospheric prices being pai dfor stocks of these companies in initial
public offerings an din exchange trading. After all, most of these
companies do not generate any earnings or even positive cash flows.
Staying ahea dof the stampede, we are moving one logical step further
by listing the value of this market share on our balance sheet as an
asset.
Every quarter we will gauge the amount of value the market is
giving us base don our market share an drecor dthat in an asset ac-
count calle dmarket share. This may seem like a “belts-and-
suspenders” policy given that our other New Accounting changes will
enable us to report actual earnings an dactual cash flows which oth-
erwise woul dbe negative. Nevertheless, we believe that this is what
shareholders an dmarket players want, an dwe are just trying to co-
operate.


160 Show Me the Money

r e c o r d i n g t h e a m o u n t o f
c a s h w e “ b u r n ” a s a n a s s e t

Companies with negative cash flows sometimes get credit for the
amount of cash they raise an dspen don researching new products.
This is especially true in the biotechnology industry, but we see no
reason why the logic of that approach shoul dnot exten dto our busi-
nesses as well. Speculators an dtraders give substantial valuation
credit for this cash burn.
Beginning today, we will treat the amount of our cash burn as an
asset on the balance sheet rather than as an expense on the income
statement. On the other hand, because of the significant impact that
the treatment of disburse dcash as an expense or an asset has on our
earnings, we reserve the right from time to time to alternate between
these treatments, depending on the tren din reporte dearnings from
quarter to quarter.

r e p o r t i n g i n a d i f f e r e n t
c u r r e n c y

We sell many of our products an dconduct a clearinghouse operation
for other businesses in a barter exchange Web site on the Internet.
In lieu of trading (or bartering) such goods an dservices directly, how-
ever, exchange members use our trademarke d“dot-com dollars,” is-
sue dto them by us for the purpose of bartering. These dot-com dollars
have a face value far greater than the U.S. dollar an dwe propose to
recor dcertain of our assets an dsales transactions in dot-com dollars
rather than U.S. dollars, thereby substantially increasing the amounts
of reporte dassets an dincome (we are not fools, however, so expenses
an dliabilities, of course, will continue to be reporte din U.S. dollars).

r e f i n i n g t h e c o n c e p t o f
m a t e r i a l i t y

Lawyers an dauditors often place great weight on whether some eco-
nomic event is material to our company or not. They define materiality
in terms of what a reasonable investor thinks about its impact on the
business or financial condition of the company. In the past, this le
us to report in our financial statements details that don’t really seem


Making (Up) Numbers 161

to matter very much to the managers at our company or to other
owners of options on our stock.
To reconcile managerial needs with the requirements of financial
reporting, the boar dadopte da new rule of materiality. Under it, no
economic activity is material to the company unless it impacts our
earnings by at least 5%. This rule is more definitive an dreliable than
the ol drule an dwill result in greater certainty in our bookkeeping
department. By applying this approach to materiality, we can ignore
a variety of burdensome reporting questions, thus saving (material)
basketfuls of money.

As satire, the report from E-America Dot.Com reveals how atro-
cious an istorte daggressive accounting an dearnings management
can be. (Most of the examples are base don actual cases.) However,
you will never see the kin dof candor expresse din this news release
coming out of corporations. That kin dof honesty is inconsistent with
the goals underlying the shenanigans.
Accordingly, you will not recognize financial disingenuousness,
recklessness, aggressiveness, deception, or frau dwhen you see it un-
less you know how to look. You will fin dthe following examples of
recent financial chicanery helpful an dwill benefit from constant pe-
rusal of the reports of financial deception chronicle dvirtually daily
in newspapers, newsletters, an dreputable Web sites.
In thinking about such charades, note that many frequently crit-
icize dtechniques are not always unlawful an o not necessarily
violate generally accepte daccounting principles. Often, however,
they impair the integrity of financial reporting. Worse, a corporate
or financial reporting culture that condones aggressive practices cre-
ates the risk of degradation of financial reporting: What starts as
merely aggressive can create pressure that leads reporting over the
line an dinto the fraudulent.
There is always pressure to engage in accounting shenanigans.
Many scandals suggest that irregular accounting is especially acute
at businesses with poor economic characteristics an dthose facing
tough competitive conditions. A company’s contractual profile may
increase pressure for aggressive or irregular accounting. Many loan
agreements, for example, contain promises by the borrower to main-
tain certain financial ratios, including debt-to-equity ratios an dthe
others discusse dearlier, an dcan lea dmanagers to meet those prom-
ises by finessing.
Incentive compensation agreements triggere dby meeting sales
or earnings targets may encourage accounting games. Similar pres-


162 Show Me the Money

sures emerge from settlement agreements, consent decrees, an dthe
other legal obligations a company faces. Planning for a itional fi-
nancing can produce pretty pictures despite dismal performance.
More generally, in an investment climate obsesse dwith short-term
results, as Levitt cautioned, there is invariably pressure to sustain
steady increases in earnings growth.

CHARADES

There are lots of aggressive accounting techniques an dopportunities
for difficult judgment calls, an dso it woul dbe surprising for any
two scandals to be identical.5 However, most accounting scandals
have a simple common denominator: Earnings are inflated. One of
the most common ways to inflate earnings is to treat as an expense
something that shoul dbe treate das an asset or a liability. This de-
ception hides the costs of doing business on the balance sheet so
that they never burden the income statement.
Dissecting most accounting scams requires only a rudimentary
understanding of simple bookkeeping rules an dtheir relationship to
financial statements. Double-entry bookkeeping requires a debit an
a credit in equal amounts for every transaction. The double entries
keep a balance sheet equalize d(assets always equal liabilities plus
net worth) an dreflect the direct relationship between income (rev-
enue minus expenses) an dnet worth.
More particularly, increases in asset or expense accounts require
debits, an ecreases in them require credits; increases in liability
or revenue accounts require credits, an ecreases in them require
debits. These bookkeeping rules are invariant, an dso short of mak-
ing up or not recording transactions, the trickery involves classifying
transactions as assets or expenses or as liabilities or revenues.

Pearson/Penguin

Consider how the Pearson conglomerate accounte dfor book sales
through its Penguin publishing division. Sales made on credit re-
quire two entries in equal amounts: a debit to Accounts Receivable,
the asset account, an da credit to Sales, the revenue account. Sub-
sequent receipt of the cash payment requires a debit to Cash an da
credit to Accounts Receivable.
Penguin began granting 10% discounts off its list price to selecte


Making (Up) Numbers 163

buyers who pai dtheir accounts early. Following bookkeeping rules,
receipt of those early cash payments calle dfor a credit to Accounts
Receivable equal to 100% of the list price. Since the buyer receive
a 10% discount on the price, the debits shoul dhave been made to
Cash for 90% of the list price, with the other 10% going to an expense
account. A ing it up, those 10% discount expenses woul dhave re-
duce dreporte dearnings.
Instea dof following these standar dbookkeeping rules, Pearson
apparently recorde dreceipts of early payments as a debit to Cash
for 90% of the list price an da credit to Accounts Receivables for
90% of the list price, an dso the 10% discount never showe dup as
an expense. It simply remaine dpart of the asset account—Accounts
Receivable—an dartificially inflate dreporte dearnings.
While Penguin’s 10% individual discounts given on a per cus-
tomer basis may at first seem like small change, they aggregate dover
six years to $163 million. Pearson’s management eventually discov-
ere dthe burie iscounts when integrating Penguin an dPearson’s
newly acquire dPutnam Berkley publishing house. Dirty bookkeep-
ing then turne dinto housecleaning.

Mercury Finance

In January 1997 Mercury Finance announce dthat it ha doverstate
earnings for the first three quarters of 1996 an dfor the whole of
1995 by a total of more than 100%. All corporate hell broke loose at
Mercury Finance, a company in the business of lending to consum-
ers with weak credit ratings. Its CEO an dcontroller both left, a
turnaroun dspecialist was recruited, an dpending deals with the
Bank of Boston an dSalomon Brothers were terminated. It lacke
cash to meet its maturing commercial paper obligations an dteetere
on the edge of bankruptcy.
The company an dthe consumer finance industry made headlines
every other day. Some commentators correctly note dthat many com-
panies in high-risk businesses like Mercury Finance’s use “aggressive
accounting techniques”; other so-calle dexperts incorrectly state
that accounting in finance companies is “extraordinary complex.” It
is not all that complex.
To lenders, loans are assets even though some loans are unlikely
to be repaid. Ba dloans are an expense—a cost of doing business.
Expenses reduce net income. Estimating the amount of ba dloans
may involve complex judgments, but the accounting is simple. The


164 Show Me the Money

portion of loans deeme duncollectible is recorde das an expense (a
debit). The credit is to an account calle dAllowance for Doubtful
Receivables.
Instea dof treating all ba dloans as expenses, Mercury Finance
apparently decide dthat even if a borrower was not going to pay,
somehow the company woul drecover the money (by repossessing
the borrower’s car, for example). In the bookkeeping, a debit was
made to an asset account calle dOther Assets to reflect the right to
repossess rather than to an expense account to reflect that the loan
probably was never going to be paid. With fewer reporte dexpenses,
Mercury Finance reporte dfar higher earnings.
A bright re dflag flew over Mercury Finance’s financial state-
ments. The Other Assets account on its balance sheet rockete dfrom
$24.6 million at the en dof 1994 to $121 million a year later. Even if
the account include dother assets besides repossession rights, the
striking increase shoul dhave seeme dpeculiar to anyone with a little
accounting sense (or even common sense).

America Online

America Online’s asset- an dexpense-flipping imbroglio resulte dfrom
treating disbursements for developing a subscriber base not as a cost
of doing business (an expense) but as an investment in the business
(an asset). While this is exactly what was done in the National Stu-
dent Marketing scandal of the late 1960s an dearly 1970s, there was
a judgment to make here.
One coul dliken on-line services to newspapers an dfollow that
industry’s practice of expensing these costs, or one coul danalogize
to direct mail order companies an dfollow that industry’s practice of
capitalizing them—treating them as assets whose cost is allocate
over future accounting periods.
In choosing between these treatments, the accounting issue is
whether the disbursements will contribute reliably to revenue gen-
eration in future periods. As it turne dout, America Online coul
not gauge for how long its new subscribers woul dremain customers,
an dso there was no basis for saying the disbursements woul din-
crease future revenue.
Maybe it was reasonable for AOL’s managers an dauditors to
make the judgment they made. After the horrible press coverage an
class action shareholder lawsuit that resulted, however, you can be
sure they regret it.


Making (Up) Numbers 165

As with Mercury Finance, a telltale re dflag flew high: AOL’s
balance sheet showe dan unusual asset calle dDeferre dSubscriber
Acquisition Costs. Mushrooming to $385 million between August
1995 an dOctober 1996, it became the largest asset on AOL’s balance
sheet. Angry shareholder agitation force dAOL to abandon the prac-
tice in the fall of 1996 an drestate its earnings, wiping out about 80%
of owners’ equity.

Fabri-Centers

Judgment plays a critical role in corporate accounting decisions, en-
abling managers to persuade auditors an irectors to accept their
position when choosing to expense or capitalize a transaction or
make other accounting decisions. Even when the managerial deci-
sion is accepted, full disclosure about the judgment shoul dbe in-
clude din the company’s financial statements but isn’t always.
If you have any doubt about the nee dfor disclosing these diffi-
cult judgment calls, consider the enlightening story behin dthe set-
tlement of SEC charges against Fabri-Centers, an operator of over
900 retail stores, including the JoAnn Fabrics chain. Fabri-Centers
knew the daily sales figures at its stores but coul dnot determine the
cost of goods sol dor the profit margin until it conducte dan annual
inventory, an dso it estimate dthem, using the so-calle dgross profit
metho dof applying the prior year’s actual profit margin to calculate
quarterly profits for the succeeding year.
During several quarters, however, heavy price competition sub-
stantially erode dthe margin. Before the erosion was reporte dor pub-
licly disclosed, the company effecte da public debt offering. The SEC
charge dFabri-Centers with inadequate disclosure about price com-
petition an dits estimation practice in that offering.
Under Fabri-Centers’ inventory system (it has since been mod-
ernized), a judgment about quarterly profit margins was necessary.
But those involve din the debt offering—aware that the quarterly
financial statements were unaudite dan dprepare din anticipation of
the offering—shoul dhave pai dgreater attention to the role that ac-
counting estimates played.

Sunbeam

Sunbeam committe da distinct but all too common type of accounting
fraud. Its widely publicize daccounting machinations boile own to


166 Show Me the Money

a series of so-calle dbill-and-hol dtransactions. During the winter
months, it recorde dcharcoal grill sales even though the grills were
not to be shippe duntil the spring. This manipulative maneuver en-
able dit to report higher sales in the winter.
The accounting shenanigan took place near the en dof the reign
of the self-proclaime dturnaroun dking Al Dunlap. Upon taking the
helm at Sunbeam—which was floundering from a substantial busi-
ness downturn—Dunlap fire dhalf its workers an dclose dor consol-
idate dmore than half its facilities. Boasting that he aime dto “attack”
his company, Dunlap declare dthat his plan was as carefully plotte
as the invasion of Normandy. (Alas, Dunlap is no Churchill, an dall
his plans for Sunbeam faile dmiserably.) With that kin dof siege
mentality driving the company, accounting irregularities might not
have been inevitable, but they were certainly made more likely.

MicroStrategy

Sunbeam’s travails of revenue recognition have sprea dthrough other
businesses, especially the computer software companies that Levitt
single dout for special illustration. One of the most dramatic ex-
amples of the potential fallout occurre dat the software company
MicroStrategy.
MicroStrategy entere dinto several unusual contracts under
which it bought an dsol dsomething from the other party. The dual
deal enable dMicroStrategy to recor drevenue much earlier than ac-
counting rules permit an dto obscure that accounting from the au-
ditors reviewing its books.
Pressure from journalists compelle dthe company an dits audi-
tors to scrutinize those contracts, an dthey ultimately decide dthe
earlier accounting ha dbeen incorrect. Shazam! When the company
finally came clean, its stock price plunge dfrom $245 to $87 per
share (over a 60% wipeout). Who lost? Popeye dshareholders.

Cendant

Obfuscatory language in corporate disclosure signifies brewing trou-
ble. This is only one of the scores of lessons learne dfrom the
notorious accounting scandal that unfolde din the late 1990s at Cen-
dant Corporation, a company forme dby the merger in late 1997 of
CUC International an dHFS Inc.
CUC operate da members-only discount shopping service that


Making (Up) Numbers 167

generate drevenue through membership dues. On average, member-
ship clubs like these earn greater profits from long-term members
than from short-term members. Indeed, the tendency is to make zero
profit from members enrolle dless than a year because they are typ-
ically entitle dto a cancellation refun dof dues.
As early as 1989, CUC met with some accounting embarrassment
for its practice of recognizing as revenue the total amount of each
membership payment in the perio dit was receive dwhile expensing
amounts allocable to each membership over a three-year period. In
bookkeeping terms, it debite drevenue while crediting both an ex-
pense account an dsome liability account, a mismatching that
booste dreporte dearnings.
Although CUC retreate dfrom that position after harsh criticism
by financial analysts an dothers, it continue dpracticing aggressive
accounting in other areas. Chief among these practices was its re-
porting technique for membership flow an dannual renewal rates—
important information for gauging company prospects given that
newer members contribute little or nothing to the bottom line while
the real value is in long-term members.
Among new members enrolle dat the en dof a given year, 70%
renewed, but the way CUC reporte dthis in its disclosure made it
seem as if 70% of all members who joine uring the year renewed.
Thus, if 100 members were in an dout during the year but 10 re-
maine dmembers at year end, the 70% figure meant that 7 renewe
even though it looke dlike 70 renewed—a tenfol ifference in the
company’s prospects.
This misleading disclosure represents only one egregious exam-
ple of numerous irregularities at the company, as a subsequent $2.8
billion settlement of an investor lawsuit an da forensic accounting
report later made clear. The report emphasize dthat these practices
manifeste dan overall culture of pernicious accounting practices.
Others include dmanipulating books relating to the percentage of
refundable membership dues, cash management, an deven how the
merger between CUC an dHFS that create dCendant was accounte
for.

CODA

Aggressive or irregular accounting is not a sign of business promise.
The trouble is, it is often har dto detect. Buffett quipped: “It has


168 Show Me the Money

been far safer to steal large sums with a pen than small sums with
a gun.”6 Steering clear of such robbery requires attention to man-
agers, who shape corporate culture. Some corporate cultures en-
courage laudable accounting practices, while others—as these chi-
caneries illustrate—encourage what Ben Graham calle
“prestidigitation” or magical numbers.7 From National Student Mar-
keting to Cendant, the question is the tone of trust at the top, which
raises the subject of the next part of this book.

P a r t I I I

IN MANAGERS
WE TRUST

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


C h a p t e r 1 1

GOING GLOBAL

arren Buffett repeatedly emphasized the importance of invest-
Wing only with people you “like, trust, and admire” (the phrase
appears over a dozen times in The Essays of Warren Buffett: Lessons
for Corporate America ). Ben Graham deemphasized this managerial
factor in investment selection, but not because he did not thin kit
was important.
Graham’s trouble was the difficulty in measuring the manage-
ment factor. He believed that until “objective, quantitative, and rea-
sonably reliable tests of managerial competence are devised and ap-
plied, this factor will continue to be looked at through a fog.”1 The
best Graham thought an investor could do to gauge the management
factor was to loo kat historical financial performance as it is reported
in financial statements.
At the same time, one of Graham’s key principles of investing as
business analysis focused squarely on integrity. Graham implored
investors not to entrust wealth to someone else unless either (1) the
investor could supervise that person or (2) the investor had “unu-
sually strong reasons for placing implicit confidence in his integrity
and ability.”2 Graham was expressly talking about investment advi-
sers, but the point applies equally to managers. After all, whether
an investor uses an intermediary or not, her wealth is in the hands
of business managers.
A fog still clouds the view of managerial ability and trustworthi-
ness, but consider two important points. First, the corporate gover-
nance field has blossomed since Graham wrote, and many people
argue that it now contributes clearer ways of thinking about and
measuring managerial integrity and effectiveness. Second, Graham
implicitly noted the importance of managerial trustworthiness when
he deferred to the financial record as a gauge of managerial ability.
As we just saw, the reliability of historical financial statements de-
pends on managerial trustworthiness.
While managerial ability and trustworthiness may not warrant an

171

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


172 In Managers We Trust

increase in your estimate of a company’s value, the weakness or
absence of these qualities certainly justifies the opposite. As Buffett
says: “Investors should pay more for a business that is lodged in the
hands of a manager with demonstrated pro-shareholder leanings
than for one in the hands of a self-interested manager marching to
a different drummer.”3
To set the stage for examining managerial integrity and ability, it
is first useful to consider the standards of behavior managers are
held to both in the United States and around the industrialized
world. Much rhetoric characterizes discussion of these conventions,
but the reality is often at odds with it. Let’s take a brief tour of the
world stage of corporate governance before zeroing in on specific
indicators of pro-shareholder management.4

THE TWO-WORLD STORY

Customarily, it is believed that corporations in the United States and
the United Kingdom (U.K.) operate primarily for the benefit of
shareholders. This contrasts with corporations in Japan, Ger-
many, and other Continental European countries, where managers
are thought to operate for the common good—for the benefit of
shareholders, workers, creditors, and communities. At an abstract
level both generalizations are correct, but on closer inspection nei-
ther is.
This comparison describes the U.S./U.K. approach as a share-
holder market model. In it, two internal groups constitute and reg-
ulate a corporation: managers and shareholders. Shareholders own
the corporation’s equity, the value of which fluctuates with the for-
tunes of the corporation. Managers consist of both the daily opera-
tors of the corporation (the officers) and those who oversee and
supervise those operations (the directors).
The key problem in U.S. and U.K. corporate governance is the
separation of ownership from control that results from the
shareholder-manager dichotomy. Two broad sets of mechanisms ad-
dress the issues raised by this problem. Monitoring mechanisms ei-
ther impose duties on managers or empower shareholders to take
action against them. Exit mechanisms include, most importantly, the
free transferability of ownership interests, which enables sharehold-
ers to sell their stoc kand thus exit the corporation at will; this often
is called the Wall Street rule.
Monitoring and exit mechanisms reinforce the financial and la-


Going Global 173

bor markets, and vice versa. Shareholders can oust inferior manage-
ments because a market for managing and controlling corporations
exists. The free transferability of ownership interests—an exit mech-
anism—has contributed to the development of deep, liquid, and ac-
tive (if not efficient) capital markets. Disclosure laws in the United
States, which promote the transparency of corporations’ perfor-
mance, have substantially aided these market forces.
Corporate transparency, coupled with the U.S./U.K. tradition of
at-will employment, also facilitates reasonably well-functioning labor
markets. For example, if managers perform poorly, corporate trans-
parency makes it more likely that shareholders will vote to oust them
and other corporations will not hire them readily.
At the same time, however, managers can contract and expand
the employee base to enhance performance. Of course, labor unions
often gain substantial power through collective bargaining agree-
ments which contract and federal labor laws protect. That power
does not derive, however, from externally imposed regulation but
instead is the product of voluntary arrangements.
Consumer product markets also contribute to the discipline of
corporate managerial performance by registering preferences which
eventually lead to corporate profits. Nonetheless, in the end, labor
markets are far from perfect, and it is not uncommon to see senior
executives earn staggering compensation despite mediocre or subpar
performance.
The great American pastime of litigation reinforces these moni-
toring mechanisms. Shareholders are equipped with a vast arsenal
of legal claims, procedural devices, and legal and equitable remedies
to protect their interests. They benefit from a specialized group of
lawyers who not only bring direct, derivative, and class action suits
under both state and federal law but also identify and communicate
the bases for such actions and even finance them.
The rights of other constituencies in a U.S. corporation differ
from those of shareholders. Contracts set employee, supplier, cred-
itor, and customer rights. The primary rationale for this treatment
is that in bankruptcy, shareholders are last in line after the claims
of all the other groups are paid off. This means that when managers
act for the shareholders they indirectly protect the interests of all
those claimants.
The central finance characteristic of this market model is frag-
mented ownership of equity securities in corporations. An underly-
ing cultural aspect of the fragmented ownership structure generates
an entrepreneurial spirit which encourages widespread participation


174 In Managers We Trust

in equity investment in terms of both those who demand it (start-
ups and expanding enterprises) and those who supply it (venture
capitalists and investors generally).
This ownership structure also rests on a cultural aversion to con-
centrations of power. The best examples are the Sherman and Clay-
ton antitrust acts that shut down trusts such as Standard Oil in the
climate of Theodore Roosevelt’s trust-busting populism. Another is
the Glass-Steagall Act, the Depression-era law that segregated the
industry of investment banking from that of commercial banking.
The repeal of that act in 1999 may reflect a degree of change in U.S.
attitudes, though it at least equally likely reflects the globalization
of the world economy, in which power is greatly diffused already;
the governmental efforts waged against Microsoft under the antitrust
laws suggest that such concerns remain prevalent.
Contrast all this with the so-called bank/labor model used to de-
scribe Japanese, German, and other Continental European corporate
systems. Instead of the shareholder market model’s fragmentation of
ownership, the central finance features of the bank/labor model are
ownership concentration and substantial investment intermediation.
Banks act as financial intermediaries by accepting individual de-
posits and compiling them for investment in corporations. Only a
relatively small number of these investing entities exist. This con-
centration of ownership and debt holdings reduces the pressure for
the development of actively functioning, deep, and liquid capital
markets. Moreover, nothing like the Glass-Steagall Act has prevented
the commercial and investment ban kunity that mitigates this con-
centration of investment ownership.
This centralization results in a small and powerful body of share-
holders and debt holders whose dual position requires few regulatory
governance mechanisms compared to the array of tools used to de-
fine the rights of various interests in U.S./U.K. corporations. Be-
cause a single ban kacts as both primary shareholder and debt
holder, there is less pressure to choose between models that favor
either shareholders or other constituencies of the corporation.
Also, less need exists for regulating governance mechanisms be-
cause of traditions that have put labor at the center of the gover-
nance structure rather than as a participant with contractually de-
fined interests. European nations are deeply committed to worker
protection, as evidenced by wage-setting policies and laws that make
firing workers difficult (in contrast to U.S./U.K. at-will employment).
These sorts of forces also explain why the disparity in compensation


Going Global 175

levels between senior executives and ordinary laborers is relatively
narrower under the bank/labor model than it is under the market
model.
In terms of formal governance, the German and Dutch version
of this model formally elevates labor as a third key participant in the
leadership of a corporation. These corporations operate with worker
councils which management must consult on a variety of matters
concerning corporate policy. German corporations generally have a
two-tiered board system which consists of a management board and
a supervisory board.
The management board (Vorstand) manages the corporation, rep-
resents it in third-party dealings, and submits regular reports to the
supervisory board. The supervisory board (Aufsichtsrat) appoints and
removes the members of the management board and oversees the
management of the corporation. Under German law, employee-
elected and shareholder-elected representatives are represented on
the supervisory board in equal shares. While it cannot make man-
agement decisions, the supervisory board may determine that certain
actions or business measures contemplated by the management
board require its prior approval.
The German dual-board structure is based on the concept of
codetermination (Mitbestimmung). According to this view, because
labor and capital codetermine a corporation’s future, labor should
protect its interests from within the corporate governance system
through formal representation on the supervisory board rather than
through contract or governmental regulation. Banks, which occupy
the unique positions of debt holder and shareholder, constitute the
other half of the supervisory board. Consequently, the separation of
ownership from control, a defining characteristic of the shareholder
market model, is expressly absent in the bank/labor model.
In the bank/labor model, even sole shareholders may lac kthe
power to remove or replace management. This lac kof power is es-
pecially pronounced under the two-tiered board structure prevalent
in Germany and the Netherlands, in large part as a result of the
wor kcouncil regulations that have been adopted across Europe. The
European Union (EU) mandates that all members except the United
Kingdom require most of their corporations to establish procedures
for employee consultation and worker council formation.
Many Continental European countries have gone beyond the EU
mandates to require that virtually all corporations establish and
maintain worker councils. Management must consult with these


176 In Managers We Trust

councils on major corporate policies affecting labor interests, in-
cluding layoff proposals and in many cases potential changes of con-
trol. Galvanizing this labor element in the corporate governance
model, the EU also requires that employment contracts follow busi-
ness assets when sold as a going concern so that a buyer of such
assets remains subject to those agreements by operation of law.
Compared to the European model, the Japanese variation deep-
ens the roles of both labor and lender banks in the governance struc-
ture. As in Europe, banks tend to own the vast bul kof the debt and
equity of industrial companies. The distinguishing factual charac-
teristic is the Japanese production model that is called horizontal
coordination. Workers are generalists when it comes to the produc-
tion process and engage in a substantial amount of information shar-
ing and training throughout production. Limited specialization, how-
ever, requires high corporate investment in labor markets to develop
the necessary human capital.
Japanese corporations thus face a higher ris kof loss on invest-
ment from worker defection than do European and American cor-
porations. However, workers face the ris kof acquiring nontrans-
portable, firm-specific skills. Corporations and workers have
addressed these risks by developing a system of lifetime employment.
This policy provides workers with permanent job security and affords
corporations a concomitantly restricted labor market.
No binding contract guaranteed this mutual security system, and
so the Japanese model turned to corporate cross-ownership to pro-
vide the necessary structural protections. Industrial corporations in
Japan own substantial percentages of the securities of other indus-
trial corporations. The resulting ownership concentration is even
more centralized than it is in the European model, and it causes a
commensurate dilution of capital market disciplining power.

ILLUSIONS OF DUTY

So much for these polar stories. Reality suggests far more overlap
and universal looseness across advanced economies in regard to the
real beneficiaries of managerial duties—an important point for in-
vestors to understand.
Corporate social responsibility remains an important dimension
of U.S. corporate governance. Direct efforts to improve the lot of
nonshareholder constituencies supplement the simple argument that


Going Global 177

shareholder-based profit maximization helps all the other partici-
pants.
Scores of organizations promote this direct approach in response
to the needs of corporate constituencies on a variety of issues, in-
cluding affirmative action, child labor, downsizing, the environment,
fair wages, privacy, sexual harassment, and the balance between wor
life and family life. These organizations operate through employee
training and assistance programs, mission statements, and social re-
sponsibility audits.
Social responsibility has reached the large organizational level.
For example, Business for Social Responsibility, an organization
founded in 1992, currently has over 1,400 corporate members with
aggregate annual revenues exceeding $1 trillion and total employees
of nearly 5 million. It features household corporate names such as
AT&T, Coke, DuPont, Federal Express, Home Depot, Motorola, and
Polaroid. Significant numbers of mutual funds and other institu-
tional investors also have committed to investing only in socially
responsible enterprises. Some investors claim that investing this way
maximizes shareholder wealth.
Many corporations have followed suit and now emphasize their
social responsibility. There are well-known exemplars of the tradi-
tional left such as Body Shop and Ben & Jerry’s (taken over by Uni-
lever in early 2000 with promises to expand the social responsibility
commitments of the global consumer products giant). There are also
some surprising followers, such as Philips-Van Heusen Corporation,
which is headed by CEO Bruce Klatsky, an adviser on U.S. trade pol-
icy to the Bush and Reagan administrations. Hasbro, Reebok, and
Wal-Mart also are following this trend. This social emphasis is entirely
consistent with state laws, which mandate that directors act in the
best interests of the shareholders and the corporation as a whole.
German law takes more seriously the idea that the beneficiaries
of directors’ duties include corporate constituents other than share-
holders, yet Germany also forbids directors from acting contrary to
shareholder interests and indeed often requires them to act in the
“aggregated shareholder interest.” German corporate law—which is
fairly representative of European countries on these points—and
U.S. law therefore contemplate the protection of all corporate con-
stituencies. Both prescribe this protection by imposing on manage-
ment the fiduciary duties care and loyalty.
The duty of care requires the exercise of an informed business
judgment, which is taken to mean that directors must gather all the


178 In Managers We Trust

material information that is reasonably available to them. Informed
directors then must act prudently and reasonably in the discharge
of their duties. The liability of directors for breach of the duty of
care in most circumstances requires a finding by a court that the
directors were grossly negligent—quite a high standard that is akin
to driving while intoxicated. The duty of loyalty requires directors to
subordinate their personal interests to those of the corporation if a
conflict exists. Specific applications of this general duty vary among
economically-developed countries, but the variation is not much
more pronounced than are the nuanced differences between states
within the United States.
The differences are thus more subtle between U.S./U.K. and
Continental Europe director duties than is often recognized. The
varying prescriptions address the content of those duties rather than
their discrete beneficiaries. They are “vertical,” intended to preserve
and expand the size of the corporate pie rather than address how it
is sliced or allocated.
When the question is pie size, the interests of managers are pit-
ted against the interests of all the other constituencies, and so it is
not surprising that these vertical mechanisms differ little across the
borders of economically advanced countries. What is surprising is
that they also extend to situations where allocation is at stake, a
“horizontal” question that manifests itself most acutely when threats
to corporate control arise.
Most U.S. state laws impose either a heightened standard of duty
on directors facing hostile takeovers or a heightened standard of
judicial review of director conduct. The issue in either instance is
whether the directors have acted in the best interest of shareholders.
While these heightened standards do not exist in German law, which
only requires directors not to act contrary to the stockholders’ in-
terest and to show regard for the common interest, this does not
mean that the heightened U.S. standard separates the American
model from the Continental model.
Many states empower directors to consider the interests of non-
shareholder constituencies in numerous circumstances. For exam-
ple, although U.S. judges often remar kthat “shareholders come
first,” they simultaneously let directors consider the impact of cor-
porate decisions on constituencies other than shareholders, includ-
ing creditors, customers, employees, and sometimes as broad a group
as the general community.
Judges sometimes mesh mandatory rhetoric with discretionary



Going Global 179

reality even in extreme circumstances such as where managers fight
against a hostile takeover—one of the devices on the horizon in the
late 1960s that Ben Graham thought might operate as a disciplining
force on underperforming managers.5 For example, in the mid-1990s
the Delaware Supreme Court accepted the arguments of Time Inc.’s
directors, who resisted an unwanted takeover by Paramount, in part
on the ground that doing so was necessary to preserve the company’s
culture of journalistic integrity. Thus, despite even the most rigorous
judicial review of board actions, in takeover contexts, directors have
a great deal of latitude.
Takeover laws do not require any particular action, such as an
auction, or impose on directors any duty to ensure that shareholders
get the highest price. The unifying inquiry in virtually all these cases
is whether a threat to the corporation exists, not solely or even nec-
essarily whether the shareholders’ interests are in jeopardy.
For a dramatic example of what occurs under laws that loo
beyond shareholder interests, consider the fight for corporate control
between AlliedSignal and AMP.6 AlliedSignal offered a 55% pre-
mium over the market price of AMP, a company whose profitability
had seriously dropped. AMP shareholders overwhelmingly supported
AlliedSignal, and within a month of the offer 72% of AMP’s out-
standing shares were tendered into it. Shareholder supporters in-
cluded the family of the company’s founder, Robert Hixon, and many
institutional shareholders, which owned approximately 80% of the
stock, including the Teachers Insurance and Annuity Association–
College Retirement Equities Fund (TIAA-CREF).
Indeed, TIAA-CREF joined a shareholder group that sued AMP’s
board. That group too kthe extraordinary step of separately filing a
“friend-of-the-court” brief supporting AlliedSignal in direct litigation
between AlliedSignal and AMP. TIAA-CREF argued that AMP had
trampled on basic “principles of shareholder democracy.”
Despite this overwhelming shareholder support for AlliedSignal,
AMP’s management successfully erected a series of defensive bar-
riers to the bid. Management too kadvantage of Pennsylvania laws
requiring directors to act in the best interests not of the sharehold-
ers, but of the corporation and permitting boards to act in what they
perceive to be the best interests of employees, lenders, communities,
and others. One extraordinary barrier AMP’s management raised
changed the terms of its “poison pill” so that it could not be elimi-
nated even by directors who held office before any of AlliedSignal’s
directors had joined.


180 In Managers We Trust

AMP sought and won an injunction prohibiting AlliedSignal’s
consent solicitation unless and until each proposed director-
candidate affirmed that if elected, he or she was duty-bound under
Pennsylvania law to act in the best interests of the corporation as a
whole, not merely in the shareholders’ interest.
The court upheld AMP’s extraordinary actions against Allied-
Signal’s claim that AMP’s board had breached its fiduciary duties in
response to the AlliedSignal bid. In its opinion, the court repeatedly
emphasized a “stakeholder” standard, which appears to be at the
heart of Pennsylvania law, and used the following unequivocal terms:
“Directors may weigh the interests of the shareholders against the
interests of other constituencies.” They “may consider the effects
upon all groups affected, including shareholders, employees, sup-
pliers, customers and creditors.” They “shall not be required to re-
gard any corporate interest or group as dominant or controlling.”
These statements do not suggest a shareholder-primacy norm. A
less obvious point but one that is equally true is that these Penn-
sylvania standards are not all that different in practice from those
of other U.S. states. They are also not all that different from German
law and may even capture the German sense of the common inter-
est.
Consider both German-based Mannesmann’s battle against the
United Kingdom’s Vodaphone and the merger of Germany’s Daimler
Benz with the United States’s Chrysler. Although German law per-
mits directors to evaluate the interests of workers and lenders and
the so-called common interest, the law also required that the board
not act contrary to the best interests of shareholders—and both
boards did so, Mannesmann’s with a vengeance.
That kind of deference to shareholders may not illustrate share-
holder primacy, nor it it consistent with the usual rhetoric of the
bank/labor model. Accordingly, U.S. practice more closely resembles
European practice than it does U.S. rhetoric, and European practice
more closely resembles U.S. practice than it does European rhetoric;
managers in neither place are obligated to hold a thoroughgoing
owner orientation.

ONE WORLD TO COME

Trends in corporate practice worldwide suggest further harmoniza-
tion, and it is a mistake for investors to overloo kthem. These trends
spell the continued erasure of differences and a tendency to make


Going Global 181

owner orientation even less compulsory. If this is the case, the al-
ready small population of true owner-orientated U.S. managers will
shrin kfurther. On the other hand, the number abroad may grow
larger.
Financial markets increasingly compete internationally, just as
product markets have done for decades. Investors (suppliers of cap-
ital) now loo kacross borders for additional investment opportunities,
while corporations and other organizations see kthe lowest-cost cap-
ital from any market in the world. The isolation of capital markets
is disappearing, and head-to-head competition among financial mar-
kets has ensued.
The EU integrates corporate finance and governance in many
respects. Most significantly, the adoption of a single currency will
harmonize competition through the sharing of productivity differ-
entials—the fruits of technological advancement and higher invest-
ment. Business expense differentials, particularly wages, should
evaporate. The process is just beginning as countries adopt the euro
and ultimately abandon their local currencies.
Nearly as profound, new EU innovations are greatly diminish-
ing barriers to cross-border capital flows. A series of EU directives
compeled the abolition of foreign investment controls. Member
states enthusiastically responded to this call by relaxing their con-
trols. The remaining restrictions generally are limited to notification
requirements or to specified sectors that pose national security or
public health, safety, and welfare concerns. Many European coun-
tries simply retained the authority to implement such controls if
necessary.

Accounting

A series of fundamental principles has harmonized accounting rules
within Europe. These principles include (1) a requirement of uniform
formats for financial statements, (2) common valuation principles,
including historical cost, accrual accounting, and the principle of
conservatism called prudence, (3) a general mandate that financial
statements show true and fair value, (4) an annual audit, (5) public
filings, and (6) consolidation principles. A trend toward unified ac-
counting reinforces the harmonization trends in finance and gover-
nance.
Similar moves have occurred in Japan. Japanese accounting rules
now require consolidation of all the accounts of a company’s con-
trolled affiliates. In the past, the absence of such a rule enabled


182 In Managers We Trust

companies to allocate the bad accounting news to affiliates, making
the parent company’s books loo kmuch better. New Japanese rules
also require listing real estate held for sale at its current market value
if that value has fallen more than 50% from the original cost. The
absence of this new rule fueled the Japanese speculative bubble of
the 1980s that cratered gradually throughout the 1990s (described in
Chapter 5).
Around the world, increasing numbers of non-U.S. and non-
English-language corporations are ahead of schedule in adopting in-
ternational accounting principles and reporting their results in the
English language. Nissan, for example, adopted consolidation ac-
counting principles in late 1999, six months ahead of schedule, and
issued related press releases about that period’s results in English,
an unimaginable act for a Japanese corporation just a decade ago
(even one that is partly French-owned).
When Nissan reported its annual financial results in mid-2000,
using international accounting principles, they showed staggering
losses of $6.3 billion. Contributing to those losses were recognition
of pension liabilities and the costs of plant closings and the assign-
ment of more realistic values to real estate and securities holdings.
Although a number of other substantive factors contributed to these
results, investors considering investment in non-U.S. companies
must understand that accounting principles elsewhere are not always
what they seem.
The United States is harmonizing its accounting principles with
those prevalent worldwide. In October 1996, Congress passed the
National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996, which re-
quires the SEC to report to Congress on progress in developing in-
ternational accounting standards. The SEC has worked with the In-
ternational Accounting Standards Committee (IASC) for nearly a
decade to promulgate a core set of accounting pronouncements. In
October 1997 the SEC published a report to Congress on the pro-
gress of the IASC, and it joined organizations throughout the world
in supporting the IASC’s initiatives.
The finance ministers and central ban kgovernors of the G7
countries proclaimed support for the IASC and encouraged it to
complete a proposed set of core principles promptly. Additionally,
the World Ban krequested the world’s “Big Five” international au-
diting firms to insist that companies prepare their financial state-
ments in accordance with international accounting standards. Lead-
ing voices from around the world, including Tony Blair, the United


Going Global 183

Kingdom’s prime minister, and Robert E. Rubin, then U.S. treasury
secretary, intoned that developing and implementing international
accounting standards is a key part of the emerging global financial
system.
The SEC argues that international accounting standards must
be comprehensive, produce comparability and transparency, provide
for full disclosure, and be amenable to rigorous interpretation and
application. Indeed, many view SEC Chairman Levitt’s broad-based
initiative to crac kdown on earnings abuses by management in U.S.
corporations as a response to the increasing attractiveness of inter-
national harmonization of accounting standards, which the SEC
wants the United States to lead rather than follow.
The future state of accounting is crucial to investors. As pliable
as accounting rules are in the United States, they remain a func-
tional way to measure business reality. Coupled with an auditing
culture that insists on the integrity of financial reporting, this system
adds unparalleled value to the investing enterprise. Investors looking
abroad should be aware of the differences and monitor improve-
ments worldwide as they pose both pitfalls and opportunities.

Governance

In Europe, periodic resistance flares up against unification efforts.
For example, 13 EU directives dealing with European company law,
as well as a proposal to create a European Corporation (Societas
Europaea) that would supplement but not substitute for the national
corporate form in individual states, were intended to promote re-
gional (if not global) harmonization. However, none of these mea-
sures is currently among the EU’s highest priorities.
On a few occasions, particularly during early EU convergence
efforts, proposals for employee board representation derailed the
adoption of some integrated governance proposals. Much of this re-
sistance originated in the United Kingdom, which has for decades
debated whether its future will be served better by a U.S./U.K. al-
liance or a Continental European EU alliance. Despite the obstacles
this uncertainty poses for EU harmony, the United Kingdom pro-
duced domestic convergence by drawing on both models.
U.S. corporate governance originally drew upon and refined U.K.
traditions. Now the United Kingdom has in turn imported those
principles as refined. Its 1992 Cadbury Report on corporate gover-
nance (renamed the Hampel Report in the final 1998 version) seeks


184 In Managers We Trust

to identify the “best practices” of global corporations. They tend to
borrow on U.S. technical innovations in corporate governance, in-
cluding some discussed in the next chapter.
The United Kingdom’s substantial role in Europe, coupled with
its lin kto U.S. corporate governance, moved the Continental models
closer to the market model. The French experience provides a pro-
vocative example. The stakeholder model and financial intermedia-
tion historically characterized French corporate governance. At the
same time, a state-dominated industrial policy defined French cap-
italism, producing firms of a smaller average size than those in other
capitalist countries and an industrial elite recruited not from within
industry but from outside it. This environment limits capital market
depth and monitoring capabilities.
Now the French model is following the trend toward globalization
and liberalism. The revisions make the French model more closely re-
semble a market model, beginning with a loosening of the state’s grip
on industry through privatization efforts. Additionally, the number of
small shareholders is rapidly growing, and, following the United King-
dom, technical governance reforms based on U.S. models have been
instituted widely. Moreover, audit and compensation committees are
forming in French corporate boards, minority shareholders are taking
on increasingly important roles, and information superior in both
quantity and quality is enhancing economic transparency.
Japan is similarly racing toward a shareholder-market model and
away from long-term employment commitments and horizontal co-
ordination. Increasingly, Japan has recognized that profit-maximizing
strategies actually are consistent with the protections its traditional
devices provide. More and more Japanese workers—particularly
younger workers—indicate that they do not intend to stay with one
employer for more than a few years at a time, let alone maintain
lifetime employment with a single firm.
U.S. corporate governance remains imperfect, as we’ll see in the
next few chapters. The principles on which it is based are sound,
but a lot can be learned from studying governance in other countries,
particularly as investors increasingly set their sites on companies
organized abroad and competing worldwide.

Mergers and Acquisitions

The Vodafone-Mannesmann fight rode a wave of American-style Eu-
ropean merger activity that erupted in early 1999 with major hostile


Going Global 185

takeover battles. In France, Banque Nationale de Paris launched a
$38 billion hostile bid to take over its two major French banking
rivals, Socie'te' Ge'ne'rale and Paribas, after they had recently an-
nounced their own plan to merge with each other. In Italy, Olivetti
launched a $60 billion hostile bid to acquire its major rival, Telecom
Italia, which in turn erected a series of substantial defensive tactics
designed to thwart the overture, including a white-knight alliance
with Germany’s Deutsche-Telecom.
In another cross-border battle, France’s LVMH Moe?t Hennessy
Louis Vuitton waged a protracted and intense battle to obtain control
of Gucci, an Italy-based but Netherlands-incorporated company
which also strenuously resisted the unwelcome overture. TOTAL-
FINA made a hostile bid for Elf Aquitaine in mid-1999, shaking up
the French industrial and governmental establishment. These kinds
of deals—in both their offensive and defensive modes—are reminis-
cent of U.S.-style merger activity, which had been unprecedented in
Europe.
Scores of friendly global alliances have reinforced the spread of
market model behavior in Europe and Japan. Led by the merger of
Daimler and Chrysler, the worldwide auto industry consolidated
through cross-border deals once considered too intractable to
achieve. Industry capacity ranges up to approximately 70 million ve-
hicles annually while average annual demand generally peaks at 50
million, and only about 10 of the world’s 40 auto manufacturers are
profitable. Some results: Ford bought control of Mazda, Volkswagen
acquired the United Kingdom’s Rolls Royce, Renault bought Sam-
sung (Korea) and a third of Nissan, and Daimler-Chrysler bought a
third of Mitsubishi.
Many other industries stand on the brin kof similar global consol-
idation. In the publishing industry, Germany’s Bertelsmann pursued
an acquiring and joint-venturing spree with other European and U.S.
counterparts; in apparel, after surviving its own battle to resist a take-
over by LVMH, Gucci too kover France’s Yves Saint Laurent; in fi-
nance, Deutsche Ban kbought Bankers Trust, UBS bought Paine
Webber, Credit Suisse bought Donaldson Lufkin Jenrette, Dresdner
bought Wasserstein Parella; British Petroleum bought Amoco; and
Nabisco and a U.S. buyout firm sought to buy Britain’s United Bis-
cuits only to be outflanked by a consortium of French, German, and
British buyers. These and scores of other proposals on the docket of
the EU merger panel have created unmatched uniformity of practices
and expectations in the corporate world.


186 In Managers We Trust

There are few ways in which a corporate board can destroy share-
holder value as dramatically as through mergers and acquisitions. As
globalization advances, more opportunities for deals arise. Some will
be desirable; many will not. Paying close attention to the activity in
this field is of great importance to investors and is addressed again
later in this part.

Capital Markets

The aggregate stoc kmarket capitalization of Europe is larger than
that of Nasdaq and over half that of the New Yor kStoc kExchange.
(Given Mr. Market, the aggregate market capitalizations can change
dramatically in short time periods, but as of early 2000, the amounts
were about $7 trillion, $4 trillion, and $11 trillion, respectively.)
The Frankfurt and London stoc kexchanges announced in July
1998 a plan to integrate their facilities and permit the trading of each
other’s listed securities on both exchanges. France, unhappy with its
exclusion, quickly gained admission to the Frankfurt-London alli-
ance (although as a 20% player, compared with 40% for each of the
founding exchanges). Soon after France announced its inclusion in
the emerging pan-European exchange, exchange officials in Milan,
Madrid, Amsterdam, and Brussels echoed a similar eagerness to par-
ticipate in the venture.
Although the European alliance had difficulty agreeing on a
common trading system, the group quickly elected to permit stoc
trading between the various exchanges. While negotiators struggled,
the once-snubbed French Bourse too kadvantage of the delays by
signing itself up with exchange partners from Amsterdam and Brus-
sels. This troika’s single market—a full integration of these three
exchanges called Euronext—boasts listings with a combined market
capitalization equal to over a quarter of that of Europe as a whole.
As the Euronext group forged this deal, the London and Frank-
furt exchanges agreed on a merger. The two formed iX, standing for
International Exchanges, a market poised to integrate blue chips and
tech stocks from the two dominant European capitals and boasting
a total capitalization of over half of that of Europe as a whole. That
deal was interrupted when OM Gruppen, operator of the Stockholm
(Sweden) stoc kexchange, made a hostile bid to buy the London
Exchange. However the dust settles on this array of parties, these
historical deals will not end capital market integration in Europe,


Going Global 187

the pace of which races on despite the presence of a dozen or more
unintegrated exchanges on the continent.
The U.S. National Association of Securities Dealers (NASD)
launched its own Nasdaq Europe stoc kmarket, one that will have
strong links to the emerging continental hybrids. This signifies a
major step toward creating a 24-hour-a-day global stoc kmarket that
began with the NASD’s similar venture in creating Nasdaq Japan, a
joint effort with the Softban kCorporation of Japan that is linked to
the Osaka Securities Exchange. All this will compel the convergence
of these markets in awesome ways, impacting finance, accounting,
disclosure, takeovers, governance, and ultimately what investors ex-
pect and what managers deliver.
Evidence of integration is pervasive in securities listing and trad-
ing. Foreign firms for years have pushed for global listing, most fa-
mously achieved by Daimler-Benz’s listing on the NYSE beginning
in 1993. These crusades continue, with rising success. After the re-
peal of Glass-Steagall, the Swiss ban kUBS filed with the SEC to
see kan NYSE listing, chiefly to give it a U.S.-listed stoc kto pay for
new acquisitions of U.S. financial services firms. This started with
its acquisition, a couple of months later, of PaineWebber.
SAP, a 25-year-old German software firm, was listed on the
NYSE in early August 1998, ten years to the day after its initial public
offering on the Frankfurt stoc kexchange. SAP is famous for gen-
erating “U.S.-style growth” and “U.S.-style rewards.” SAP executives
characterized its listing on the NYSE as evidence that SAP had “out-
grown” the Frankfurt stoc kmarket and evolved into a transnational
company combining features of a variety of governance models.
Clear-cut signs of the conglomeration of international securities
trading include the creation of the International Securities Exchange
(ISE) for options trading. An on-line brokerage firm, E*Trade, and
a group of broker-dealers led by Adirondac kTrading Partners in-
vested nearly $80 million to establish this all-electronic options
exchange. The founders touted their ability to slash transaction costs
while simultaneously conducting staggering sums of electronic
trades which transcend geographic boundaries.
Investors should not ignore the shape of capital markets. How
trades are made, by whom, at what cost, and over what time periods
significantly affect price volatility and have an impact on market
efficiency. Equally important, exchange rules often dictate account-
ing requirements, and so the ease of international listings can impair
the integrity of financial reporting.


188 In Managers We Trust

The Last Frontier: Information

A practical barrier to cross-border deals has been yielding. It con-
cerns the nature and amount of available information regarding a
counterparty. In market model countries such as the United States
and the United Kingdom, a wealth of information is available con-
cerning the targets organized therein. These countries tend to op-
erate systems of public recordation for real as well as intellectual
property. Well-developed securities and mergers and acquisitions
(M&A) industries strengthen such an information culture.
Buyers and sellers in M&A transactions understand the need for
information to allow proper valuations and the need for contractual
protection to preserve confidentiality. Sellers customarily meet these
needs by executing confidentiality agreements early in the explora-
tion process and providing the buyer with substantial proprietary
data before discussing agreements any further.
The culture in European and Asian countries contrasts remark-
ably with that of the U.S./U.K. market model. Access to property
records is limited, and information is more jealously guarded. Sellers
are reluctant to share information with a potential buyer who can
wal kaway from a deal if she doesn’t like what she sees; confidenti-
ality agreements that protect such a seller in the United States and
the United Kingdom simply don’t do the trick. That may be sensible,
since a less well-developed system of legal enforcement for such
agreements justifies a seller’s apprehension about a buyer’s confi-
dentiality.
Cultural disparities became acute in the Vodafone-Mannesmann
battle. Mannesmann sued Vodaphone’s adviser, Goldman Sachs, in
a U.K. court, trying to prevent it from advising Vodaphone on the
grounds that Goldman had previously represented Mannesmann and
possessed confidential information about it. The British court dis-
missed the lawsuit after a brief hearing and in a short time, basically
telling Mannesmann that its claim was frivolous.
Substantively, the type of information understood as relevant also
varies between the models. In the market model and especially in
the United States, disclosing potential environmental or retiree lia-
bilities is a time-honored practice. Other countries have only re-
cently developed environmental regulation. Also, other countries tra-
ditionally rely more heavily on public social security systems,
removing private plans from center stage (even in countries such as
Germany, where such liabilities are often substantial and unfunded).


Going Global 189

For investors, U.S. corporations disclose far more than do those
in Europe or Japan. U.S. federal and state law, as well as stoc
exchange rules and general market pressures and expectations in the
United States, result in corporations disclosing extraordinary
amounts and types of information. Other countries impose more
limited and far less effective disclosure requirements.
As global corporations as diverse as DaimlerChrysler and SAP
increasingly list shares on U.S. stoc kexchanges and stoc kexchanges
around the world, they will find themselves subject to U.S.-style dis-
closure requirements as a matter of both regulatory mandate and
market expectations and demand. As the same group consummates
cross-border transactions requiring the disclosure and evaluation of
information, pressures toward uniform disclosure requirements will
emerge in a wide variety of settings. In fact, participants find that
U.S./U.K.-style information disclosure is consistent with existing
corporate traditions in most countries, most notably Germany. Ac-
cordingly, broadening global corporate laws to require such disclo-
sure seems quite possible.
Public regulators have undertaken just such an effort. The SEC
is working with the International Organization of Securities Com-
missions (IOSCO) to develop a set of international standards for
nonfinancial statement disclosure. These efforts are intended to fa-
cilitate cross-border financing and listing by transnational companies
while holding them to a single global standard of disclosure. The
IOSCO issued new rules about certain kinds of cash transactions
and offerings and listings of common equity securities and is working
to extend them to tender and exchange offers, business combina-
tions, privatizations, and other affiliated deals.
High-quality information is essential for intelligent investing in
the modern global marketplace. Ignoring the garbage and disinfor-
mation piling up on the Internet is becoming increasingly difficult
as more countries develop information-based corporate and investing
cultures and as more citizens of those countries learn the ropes of
the systems.

Two-Way Street

Not all these trends run one way, for the idea of shareholder primacy
in the United States was gradually but substantially eroded by the
dramatic reallocation of corporate value from shareholders to work-


190 In Managers We Trust

ers throughout the latter half of the twentieth century. In the past,
workers had no interest in a corporation other than a paychec kand
the right to quit (and be fired). Today corporations whose workers
have no interest except a paychec kare rare.
Workers have claims against their corporate employers ranging
from vacation and sic kpay to paternity or maternity leave, safety and
antidiscrimination rights, health plans, severance claims, and retiree
benefits and pensions. All these claims cost substantial amounts of
money, value that in the old days was owned by the shareholders.
On top of all that, somewhat paradoxically, employees have become
shareholders of these corporations and, counter to the Japanese
trend, are actually staying with the same employer for longer periods
and expressing greater loyalty to their employers than they did in the
past.
U.S. regulators are taking pages from abroad in a bolder way. A
major example is the elimination of boundaries between investment
and commercial banking. These boundaries were relaxed in Decem-
ber 1996, when the Federal Reserve Board increased the amount of
investment banking income a commercial ban kcan earn from in-
vestment banking subsidiaries from 10% to 25%. The so-called Sec-
tion 20 subs ushered in this regulatory change, which contributed
substantially to the ensuing wave of commercial and investment
ban kmergers and reversed a historical cause of ownership fragmen-
tation. The repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act in November 1999 has
further fueled such financial reunions.
The U.S. litigation system is not the envy of the world, and it
encourages large volumes of shareholder class action and derivative
lawsuits against management. In contrast, most legal systems put
substantial restrictions on such suits. Although it does not appear
that litigation will decline substantially in the United States, it is
clear that lawmakers want to curb litigation abuse. For example, the
Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995 substantially revised
the securities laws in an effort to distinguish frivolous claims from
meritorious ones.

This analysis forecasts the hybridization of corporate governance
models in terms of both constituency and finance characteristics.
No owner orientation is required by these models. Forces appear to
be pushing for convergence, and the emerging model will not require
an owner orientation either. Indeed, to the extent that there is any-
thing real to the European corporate governance rhetoric, conver-


Going Global 191

gence will dilute rather than enhance any managerial mandate to
run U.S. corporations mainly for the benefit of shareholders. De-
tecting an owner orientation in this global marketplace thus becomes
more important than ever.
Buffett tells us that the most valuable lesson he learned in in-
vesting was realizing the importance of owner-oriented managers.
The value of this timeless lesson will increase geometrically in a
globalized world. Of course, Buffett emphasizes that while manage-
ment quality can dramatically affect returns on equity, it is never a
substitute for a good business within one’s circle of competence,
saying that “a good managerial record (measured by economic re-
turns) is far more a function of what business boat you get into than
it is of how effectively you row (though intelligence and effort help
considerably, of course, in any business, good or bad).”7 The re-
maining chapters focus on identifying winning managers.


C h a p t e r 1 2

RULES AND TRUST

n investor is going to entrust her wealth to someone else.
AShouldn’t the investor have a high degree of confidence in that
person’s ability and integrity? Of course. It is simple common sense,
but how to assess ability and integrity is a bit trickier.
Graham used the quantitative analysis of the sort described in
Part II as a proxy. If the numbers loo kgood year after year and
provide a basis for thinking that they will continue to do so, that
may suggest that management is able.
Many other investors, including Warren Buffett in his early days,
learned hard lessons from paying too little attention to management
integrity. True, if a company’s numbers loo kgood and are accurate,
its managers are probably able and trustworthy. If the numbers loo
good but are misleading, management may be neither. As Buffett
reminds us, “In the long run, managements stressing accounting
appearances over economic substance usually achieve little of ei-
ther.”1
Therefore, integrity is an additional independent factor in in-
vestment selection. Is there a sensible way to thin kabout managerial
integrity? Buffett says the key is to invest with managers you “like,
trust, and admire.” His test for whether an investment meets this
requirement is whether the managers are “men you would be pleased
to see your daughter marry.”2
Does this “son-in-law” standard help? It may only suggest avoid-
ing managers you would not be pleased to invite over for a Super
Bowl party, but this is a great deal more meaningful than it sounds.

THE FAMILY MANAGER

All business transactions depend on trust and always have. Contracts
help define and protect rights, but entering into one calls for some
expectation that the other party will do what he says he will do.

193

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


194 In Managers We Trust

Contracts also reduce the costs of doing business and investing by
enabling people to trade off future risks, but that works only if the
other person can be expected to live up to the deal.
Trust in business is deeply rooted in kinship, and so it is no
wonder that the son-in-law test makes sense. The lin kbetween the
son-in-law test for managers and business itself comports with the
broad history of business development. Most businesses start out as
family enterprises and then grow in size over decades or generations,
adding relatives to the management ranks (often even including
sons-in-law, as at Anheuser-Busch, the Washington Post Company,
and Mead, for example). In many cases, such growth leads families
to give up control and the business evolves into a modern corpora-
tion, as occurred at Brown-Forman, DuPont, Eli Lilly, McGraw-Hill,
Nordstroms, and countless others.
The erstwhile family business as modern corporation no longer
has Dad or Granddad or Daughter at the helm but instead has a
cadre of professional managers, a diffusion of control, an institu-
tionalized organizational structure, and lines of reporting authority.
The upshot is a corporation characterized by a separation of own-
ership from control—shareholders watching managers run the busi-
ness. Trust in the modern corporation should resonate with norms
and values associated with that family business.
It is rarely feasible for an individual investor to sit down and get
acquainted with the chief executive officers of most major corpora-
tions, but all these chiefs write annual letters to shareholders and
author other addresses periodically as well. These communications
contain remarkable clues about trustworthiness. The manager’s own
words often reveal her character. (Chapter 14 pursues this point.)
What is it that you trust a manager to do? The answer to that
question comes from thinking of him as your manager, something
that is hardly ever done. People always spea kof their broker, their
accountant, their lawyer, but they hardly ever spea kof their manager.
Yet a corporate manager does just as much for your wealth as these
sidekicks do, or more.
What should your manager do? Run the business for your ben-
efit, as a shareholder, against the numerous and often conflicting
interests of other constituencies of the business. Here is another key
point that is often overlooked: The perspectives of investors and
managers often diverge. When they do, investor interests can be
disserved.


Rules and Trust 195

Managers raise funds for corporate enterprise from the investing
public in the form of equity capital or stocks. Investors are regarded
by managers either as partners in the enterprise or merely as con-
sumers.
When seen as consumers, investors are deemed to have tastes
and preferences that are reflected in the prices at which managers
can sell them stocks and other securities. Most of these investors
have little or no say in how a business is operated or even who the
managers will be (other than through annual elections of directors).
Instead they are strangers to the corporation, strangers whose
interests are subordinated to those of the corporation as a whole. In
this type of corporation, for example, managers tend to consider the
tax effects of declaring a dividend or structuring an acquisition deal
on the corporation as a whole but not on the individual shareholders.
In contrast, the voices of individual investors matter more to
owner-oriented managers. Seeing them as partners in the business,
these managers treat investors as members of the enterprise rather
than as strangers to it. Electing directors remains the formal vehicle
for this voice, but a more solicitous view of owner interests is taken.
For example, these managers consider the tax effects of corporate
decisions such as dividends and deals on the investor rather than
on, or at least separately from, the corporation.
It is far easier for managers of family and other small and pri-
vately held corporations to adopt this owner orientation. It is far
easier for managers of large publicly held corporations to adopt the
opposite view. The managers with whom intelligent investors should
entrust their wealth are those who adopt the investor’s perspective
no matter how large the corporation or how many shareholders it
has.

LOCAL GOVERNANCE

The reality of global corporate management means that boards and
managers can run a business for the benefit of many constituencies,
not solely shareholders. Laws permit managers to operate pretty
much wherever they want along the spectrum from a shareholder
orientation to a constituency orientation. One part of business anal-
ysis is evaluating the degree to which management has an owner
orientation.


196 In Managers We Trust

Sources for determining that orientation abound, probably more
so in the United States but increasingly throughout the developed
world. In the United States, corporations disclose volumes of infor-
mation to shareholders and other interested people. Many corpora-
tions go beyond legal requirements, producing substantial informa-
tion on their Web sites and Webcasting archives and you can get
plenty of high-quality and reliable information from publications by
reputable industry analysts such as Standard & Poor’s, Dun & Brad-
street, and Robert Morris Associates as well as government agencies
such as the Federal Trade Commission. Use your imagination.
Sift through these materials in looking for managers who act like
stewards of shareholder capital. Use it to find the best managers,
those who thin klike owners in making business decisions and who
adopt an attitude of partnership, embracing shareholders as mem-
bers of the enterprise rather than as strangers to it, those you would
be happy to invite over for a Super Bowl party.
However, even owner-oriented managers sometimes have inter-
ests that conflict with those of shareholders. Wor kto identify and
invest with those who make a habit of easing those conflicts and
nurturing managerial stewardship of owner funds, those who exhibit
Aristotelian ethical virtue.
It is not easy to detect governance indicators of an owner ori-
entation in place at a corporation any more than it is to detect the
financial or managerial performance or even value of a corporation
from its financial statements. However, as with that effort, it is worth
the work.
The difficulty and the possibility exist because the law requires
very little of corporate governance. Yes, federal securities laws im-
pose extensive disclosure obligations, though most of what they call
for probably would be produced voluntarily by good companies par-
ticipating in a vibrant market economy anyway. Yes, state laws im-
pose duties on directors and managers, but those duties are loose
and general. Some statutory rules or limits are imposed, but they
are either highly formal and therefore malleable or pretty meaning-
less as a practical matter and can be altered in corporate by-laws or
charter documents.
Corporate governance as such is not necessary. Many advocates
of corporate governance argue for reforms directed toward compel-
ling an owner orientation, usually described as aligning management
and shareholder interests or enhancing board oversight of CEO per-
formance. If a company needs these mechanisms to create an owner


Rules and Trust 197

orientation, however, its valuation should be discounted proportion-
ally.
Most corporate governance reforms fail to solve governance
problems, and some exacerbate them. Nevertheless, institutional in-
vestors and other shareholder advocates have promulgated a variety
of policies about corporate governance, most of which are designed
to promote an owner orientation. But just as fads infect finance,
they gum up governance too.
Perhaps the most popular governance idea in the past couple of
decades has been the call for independent boards of directors. The
National Association of Corporate Directors (NACD) and many in-
stitutional investors including CalPers and TIAA-CREF, urged that
corporate boards be composed of at least a majority of outside di-
rectors, those without employment or other affiliation with the cor-
poration. The idea was that this would strengthen directorial spines
to keep management in check. Nearly all major companies fell into
line, with 90% of Fortune 1000 companies having a majority of in-
dependent directors.
These arguments were made on the basis of intuition, however,
rather than analysis. It was as if there were little or no doubt that
managers needed to be kept in line and that director watchdogs
could do the trick. This premise has been exploded by several studies
showing that far from independent boards enhancing economic per-
formance, there is actually a negative correlation between the degree
of independence and financial results.3
This is not to say that having some or many independent direc-
tors is never desirable (Buffett, for example, believes that most di-
rectors should be outsiders),4 but there is no reason to give credit
ipso facto to a company just because it does this. The unanswered
commonsense questions are: (1) Who are these independent direc-
tors? and (2) What value do they add to the boardroom? Independent
directors famous for international diplomacy or senatorial jobbery
may be far worse to have at the table than a chief financial officer
with extensive industry and managerial experience. A template that
calls for independence is not a virtue but a mirage.
The key is to choose directors for their business savvy, interest
in the job, and owner orientation. To be avoided are celebrity direc-
tors and others who are chosen for nonfundamental reasons, such
as adding diversity or prominence to a board.
Another popular move some companies fell for was the push to
split the functions of the company’s CEO from those of its board


198 In Managers We Trust

chairman. This manifested the same rationale of independence pre-
scriptions, a need to chec kthe boardroom power of the CEO. Only
about 5% of Fortune 1000 companies succumbed to this formula,
probably with good reason.
As an empirical matter, as with board independence, most evi-
dence shows that companies that split these functions do not per-
form better than those which do not.5 As an abstract matter, it is
hard to justify giving a company governance credit for this separation
of function, for putting a watchdog on the CEO suggests as many rea-
sons to be suspicious of the CEO as reasons to trust him. For a com-
pany whose CEO is not to be trusted, this may be a good step, but
it sounds more like probation than probity and is a strong warning
signal for investors to run from rather than embrace the business.
Only a fool, after all, thinks trust can be purchased or structured.
One aspect of this reform makes sense, however, and many com-
panies adopted a version of it by providing for a nonexecutive board
chair for critical functions such as CEO, board, and director eval-
uations. After all, letting the CEO grade herself and her board does
pose a ris kof self-delusion. An independent grader is in a better
position to evaluate performance objectively, and so some gover-
nance credit is justified for a company that takes this step.
Director independence is frequently encouraged for some com-
mittees and often required for audit committees. Audit committee
independence is consistent with the structure of U.S. audit practice
that requires an auditing firm to be independent of the company and
its management. Independence on compensation committees re-
flects the logic of a nonexecutive overseer for key functions such as
CEO and board performance review.
However, the argument for requiring independence on other
committees, such as nominating, ethics, and governance, is the same
as that for independence overall. If a corporation needs those kinds
of things, it has problems anyway. The mere fact that a corporation
has various independent board committees does not guarantee that
problems arising from collusion or delusion will be absent or dis-
appear.
Periodic and formal evaluations of the CEO and other directors
are often recommended and do seem sensible and worthy of praise.
To deserve credit, however, the CEO reviews should be conducted
outside the presence of the CEO, something that is not easily or
commonly done. A more general way to implement this practice is
to supplement such periodic reviews with regular director meetings


Rules and Trust 199

outside the CEO’s presence, a practice Buffett in particular cham-
pions. This is creditworthy not so much under the logic of suspicion
of the CEO but as an independent chec kon the CEO’s judgment.
Some gobbledygoo kabout improved board processes is com-
monly bandied about. This is usually sheer nonsense or gloss. Re-
quirements such as swift flows of quality information, statements of
governance principles, and procedures for full and effective partici-
pation of all directors seem like mere bafflegab. These practices
should simply be part of the normal operation of a well-governed
corporation. Giving credit for the articulation of these practices is
superfluous—like giving umpires extra credit for knowing the rules
of baseball.
Other common and strange prescriptions take pages from the
equally silly playboo kof American politics. Term limits for directors?
Why should a good director be forbidden from continuing in his job
just because he’s done it for a specified period of time? Age limits?
Nearly 40% of Fortune 1000 companies adopted age limits in re-
sponse to urgings from governance poobahs such as CalPers.
But a company that forbids persons older than, say, 65 or 70 is
ordaining the exclusion of talent from its reach. One can applaud
Jac kBogle for stepping down as Vanguard’s chairman at the fund’s
mandated retirement age of 70, but is Vanguard really better off
without Jac kor any other (old!) sagacious person with integrity? And
what should it matter—on its own terms—that 5 of the 18 members
of Disney’s board are in their seventies, if those people are savvy
business leaders who see kto promote the interests of Disney’s own-
ers?
At the other end of the politically correct scale of corporate gov-
ernance is the goal of trying to add diversity of gender or race to the
board. Diversity itself is not a laudable business goal and is nothing
for which credit should be given to the leaders of a business orga-
nization. It is just as out of place, silly, and off the mar kas delib-
erately creating and maintaining a diversified portfolio of stocks. It
may turn out to be fine and dandy, but if so, that is a consequence
and not a cause of a more prudent disposition that focuses on fun-
damentals rather than frames. It does not matter one way or the
other that GE’s board has two women and one blac kperson on it
though it does matter that those people and GE’s other directors are
outstanding business thinkers with a strong owner orientation.
The problem with all these sorts of proposals is their universality.
What is good for GM may not be good for GE, and what is good for


200 In Managers We Trust

either of them may not be good for Procter & Gamble or eBay, Wrig-
ley, or Hershey. Each corporate situation justifies and calls for its
own governance structure and analysis. Broad credit can be given
only for governance moves that have some inherently defensible
logic, such as having the board review the CEO’s performance with-
out her being present and having independence on the audit com-
mittee.
Beyond that, these general principles are of little use. Indeed,
too much emphasis on them can be affirmatively misleading. You
can put all the governance bells and whistles you want on a board,
but if its CEO or other strong leaders lac kintegrity, you can be sure
they will neither ring nor blow.

GENERAL GOVERNANCE

While one-size-fits-all recipes of corporate governance are inapt, a
few areas justify generalizations. The most important is that active
boards engaged with the companies they serve boost corporate per-
formance. That is plain common sense, though empirical studies
confirm the intuition.6
A key problem in all governance structures is the size of the
board. You do need a minimum number of directors to generate the
kind of thoughtful deliberateness that characterizes any effective
group of people. But above that number—which is probably as low
as six—the larger the board is, the less manageable it is. Lean is
mean in business, and there is no question that ideas and energy
move more quickly through leaner managerial structures, as Wal-
Mart proved to Sears and GE proved to Westinghouse. Smaller
boards often translate into leaner management teams down the
ranks.
A similar problem is the number of other boards on which in-
dividual directors serve. The more duties a given director undertakes
in various companies, the less effective she is likely to be on each
one. A director’s concurrent experience on two boards may add value
to both. Former U.S. Senator Sam Nunn serves on the boards of a
half dozen public companies (including GE, Coke, and Texaco), for
example, and his wor kon one may benefit the needs of the others.
But how effective is a director who serves on a dozen boards at once?
Vernon Jordan serves on nearly that many and has been criticized
for doing so. It would be a rare person whose prominence and trust-


Rules and Trust 201

worthiness, not to mention access to the corridors of power, could
remain valuable to a company that shares her service with so many others.
 A final point all corporations should worry about is who is nextin line for the top spot.  

It may not be necessary for a company to have a formal succession plan for its CEO, but it is important for

the board to give it some thought.

The trouble is that even the best laid plan can go awry and sometimes the most surprising and unplanned succession can have terrific benefits.

Succession is a matter

of judgment, and just because a board has thought hard about it, that doesn’t mean its plan will wor k(more on this in the next chapter).
 All these details of corporate governance provide clues aboutmanagerial trustworthiness.  

A board filled with close personal

friends of the CEO who lac ksolid business backgrounds is a redflag of caution. 

A board that fails to review the chief’s performanceregularly may not be trustworthy either.

Take another area of cor-

porate life: charitable giving.

If most of the corporation’s charitable

contributions go to pet causes of the CEO, maybe you should won-
der whether he treats the corporation more as his than as yours.
Unique among major American corporations, Berkshire Hathaway
rejects managerial direction of discretionary charitable giving, put-
ting this power directly in the hands of shareholders.7
If these factors indicate high trustworthiness, lower your dis-

count rate on a good business;

if they suggest moderate trustworthiness, raise it upward.  

(If they suggest an antiowner orientation,

simply stay away.)

Amid the intense interest in corporate governance there gener-
ally emerges the subtopic of corporate governance for Internet com-

panies.

Some argue that the traditional templates of corporate gov-

ernance simply do not apply to new economy companies.

It is hard

to see exactly why, but the argument seems to be that the speed of
industry change, the intensity of competition, the shortage of
technology-savvy managers, and the importance of stoc koptions in
compensation packages mean that the new economy cannot abide

the old rules and ways.

8

These arguments are silly.

On their face, they state very little

difference in the problems of governing a new economy company

versus an old economy company.

Change, competition, managerial

savvy, and incentive compensation matter in all businesses.

A better



202 In Managers We Trust

argument would relate these different sorts of companies to their

respective average sizes.

Smaller companies may need or warrant less

in the way of formal governance (such as board review of director

performance) than do larger companies.

But that argument relates

to the dot-com governance debate only to the extent that dot-coms
are on average smaller than non-dot-coms, something that may or
may not be true and so is ultimately irrelevant.
The key issue for any kind of business also remains the same,
whether new economy, old economy, future economy, or whatever.
It is what constitutes good governance, and the answer varies with
company specifics, including potentially to which category a com-
pany belongs. Just as a one-size-fits-all governance template is in-
appropriate for the run of non-dot-com companies, it is inappropri-
ate for dot-coms.
In fairness to the advocates of new governance rules for new
economy companies, they were forced into this strange stance (that
dot-coms as a group were both alike and special) because governance
gurus had so whipsawed old economy companies into governance
uniformity that prevailing governance practices did not make sense
for many dot-coms (for the same reasons they never made sense for
many old economy companies).
It is therefore a colossal waste of time even to discuss whether
governance principles should be different. Of course they should,
but not because of anything special about dot-coms as such but
instead because every business organization is special.

YOUR VOICE A HE TABLE

Persuading boards to listen to shareholders is an ideal corporate gov-
ernance method, but legal and practical limits frustrate this simple
vehicle. Apathy and collective action problems limit the sharehold-
ers’ voice, but this explains only part of the problem.
Most state laws authorize corporations to establish procedures
governing shareholder proposals at annual or special meetings. The
SEC imposes additional rules.9 As a matter of practice, management
on average strongly prefers rules that enable it to omit shareholder
proposals from proxy statements.
Using the “shareholder proposal rule” has led to substantial pol-
icy changes at many major corporations. For example, beginning in


Rules and Trust 203

the 1930s, this rule was used to enhance shareholder rights in areas
such as cumulative voting and dissemination of postmeeting reports.
Virtually anyone can satisfy the eligibility requirements for com-
pelling a corporation to include a shareholder proposal in the cor-
poration’s annual proxy statement. By law it is enough to own 1% or
$1,000 in market value of the corporation’s equity for one year, and
the costs of making proposals are borne by the company.
Shareholder proposals are often made by only nominal share-
holders, spearheaded by nonshareholder constituencies that harness
the shareholder proposal rule to effect social change. (This use ex-
ploded in the 1970s, with the famous Campaign GM that led to the
integration of GM’s board of directors.) Social policy advocates use
it to promote things such as reporting requirements concerning the
environmental impact of corporate actions, race and sex discrimi-
nation, and human rights activities. Sometimes these are in the in-
terests of shareholders, and sometimes they are not.
In the last few decades shareholders and other constituencies
have employed this device innumerable times. Although most cam-
paigns do not carry a majority vote, increasing numbers of proposals
win. But because everyone knows nominal shareholders can make
proposals, management can take lightly even proposals that win the
support of a majority of shareholders. Thus management often opts
not to implement a winning proposal. After all, if management be-
lieves in the proposal, it will adopt it without waiting for a constit-
uency initiative or vote.
More important than the shareholder proposal rule is the pos-
sibility of a corporate takeover. This can be effected either by proxy
contest or by tender offer. In a proxy contest, the more traditional
method of corporate takeover, a shareholder or group of shareholders
appeals to other shareholders to change control of the company by
electing new directors to the board. They argue their case in a proxy
statement delivered to all shareholders, and the incumbent group
presents its case in its own proxy statement. The shareholders vote,
and their voice is heard.
Before the late 1960s and early 1970s, Ben Graham lamented the
difficulty shareholders faced in changing poor management in this
way. (Graham knew firsthand about those difficulties, for he waged
a proxy contest to wrest control of a company earlier in his career.)10
But proxy contests became far easier to wage and more effective in
that time, signaling the dawn of the corporate governance movement
that too kfirm hold in the 1980s. As a consequence of the rise in


204 In Managers We Trust

proxy contests in the late 1960s and early 1970s, Graham said that
“boards of directors have probably become more alive than previ-
ously to their fundamental duty to see that their company has a
satisfactory top management.”
The 1980s brought more sophisticated and better-funded takeo-
ver tactics to corporate America, chiefly the tender offer, by which
shareholders simply exit a company with unsatisfactory management
and performance. The result has been the creation of a market for
control of corporations, a way to give real meaning to the share-
holders’ voice. Thus, Graham’s plea made at the dawn of the cor-
porate governance era assumes greater value now: “that stockholders
consider with an open mind and with careful attention any proxy
material sent them by fellow stockholders who want to remedy an
obviously unsatisfactory management situation in the company.”11


C h a p t e r 1 3

DIRECTORS AT
WORK

n increasingly common lament sung across corporate America
Ais that directors are overworked. They are asked to do too much,
must satisfy too many competing interests, and so on. There is a
simple and sufficient solution to this condition. Directors should be
asked to do a short list of five things and do them well. The key jobs
entrusted to any board of directors are as follows:

• Selecting an effective chief executive
• Setting executive compensation
• Evaluating takeovers
• Allocating capital
• Promoting integrity in financial reporting

Effective performance of these jobs ultimately depends not so
much on governance mechanisms as on board trustworthiness. An
investor should pay attention to how well directors perform these
tasks as a way to gauge where along the continuum from owner
orientation to manager orientation they sit. A management-oriented
position is suggested by fat executive paychecks for a dismal perfor-
mance. A stakeholder-oriented position reveals itself in poor returns
on invested capital that keep unproductive plants operating in a bow
to labor pressure. An owner orientation is reflected by good perfor-
mance, reasonable executive pay, and the cultivation of productive
workers in productive jobs.
As a management orientation example, as kyourself whose inter-
ests were really going to be served by AMP’s resistance to Allied-
Signal’s bid discussed in Chapter 11? AMP’s shareholders objected,
and so they obviously thought their interests were being disserved,
and AMP’s plan to boost the company’s profitability included cutting

205

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


206 In Managers We Trust

the wor kforce by about 9%, or 4200 jobs, and closing ten factories.1
AMP’s board ultimately may have served the corporation’s interests
in concluding a deal with a friendly partner, but AMP’s CEO and
management undoubtedly pressured the board to resist what by all
accounts looked good for shareholders in favor of something that
looked bad for the workers.
The best way to tell where a company sits is to investigate the
way its directors tackle their key jobs. Focus on those jobs and decide
which boards do them well.

HAIL TO THE CHIEF

The CEO sets the tone at the top. The CEO’s historical performance
on matters such as compensation, acquisitions, and capital alloca-
tion generally is the key question an investor should as kwhen judg-
ing a CEO and deciding whether to entrust wealth to his or her
management. Special attention must be paid to selecting a CEO
because of his or her unique role in the organization.
Warren Buffett notes that standards for measuring a CEO’s per-
formance are either inadequate or easy to manipulate, and so a
CEO’s performance is harder to measure than that of most workers.
The CEO has no senior other than in theory the company’s board
of directors. That board is often handicapped in its performance
review, however, because of a lac kof measurement standards and
because as meetings come and go, the relationship between the CEO
and the directors increasingly becomes congenial rather than super-
visory.
Maintaining that supervisory attitude is critical. The board’s role
in reviewing the CEO’s performance is most acute precisely where
it can be most easily impaired: dealing with a mediocre manager. It
is easy for a board to get rid of a terrible manager; the hard case is
a so-so one. Recruiting the top talent and a roster of succession
candidates is a critical board function. Too often the importance of
this role is overlooked, as occurs when a board simply replaces an
outgoing CEO with the number two fellow at the company (which
happens about two-thirds of the time). This means that many boards
fail to evaluate changing organizational needs and variations in the
personal talents of the two at the top.2
Abdication of a board’s responsibility for CEO selection is most
clear when a board simply allows an incumbent CEO to handpic


Directors at Work 207

the successor. There is little reason to believe that even the most
outstanding CEO is as good as a top board at picking a new CEO.
The result is too often the need to oust the new CEO pretty early
in his or her tenure.
Still, boards must evaluate a CEO’s performance regularly and
out of the CEO’s presence, and evaluating that performance is hard-
er than it seems. Both short-term results and potential long-term
results must be assessed. If only short-term results mattered, many
managerial decisions would be much easier, particularly those relat-
ing to businesses whose economic characteristics have eroded.
Recall again Al Dunlap’s aggressive and doomed plan to turn
around the ailing Sunbeam. The huge accounting scandal that fol-
lowed in its wake also suggests its inherent stupidity. Once it was
clear that Dunlap was a terrible manager, it was easy for the Sun-
beam board to throw him out, but before the fallout he looked at
worst mediocre and therefore harder to disagree with.

PAY

Plenty of evidence shows that the total level of executive compen-
sation in the United States is positively correlated with the level of
corporate performance. Some evidence even shows a positive cor-
relation between performance and the portion of total compensation
paid in stock.3
Even so, it is also obvious that some executives are paid sub-
stantially more than they should be in light of their performance.
Accordingly, investors should pay close attention to potentially pi-
ratical executive compensation.

Compensation Levels

This is not to say that it is desirable to have governance rules that
limit top executive compensation to some ratio of the pay of the
least compensated employee at a company. Indeed, Ben & Jerry’s
tried this during its early years of business life, capping its founder’s
and chief’s compensation at seven times that of the lowest-paid
worker. But once the company outgrew its founder’s managerial
skills, it was forced to go on the market to recruit top talent, and
that required a pay package way higher than that cap.4


208 In Managers We Trust

If the early Ben & Jerry’s policy showed bad judgment, some of
the pay packages seen lately show something far worse. The CEO
of Networ kAssociates (owner of the McAfee computer antivirus pro-
grams), for example, got about $7 million in shares of McAfee.com
just ahead of its IPO even though the business of Networ kAssoci-
ates performed poorly and McAfee itself was losing money.5
A key issue in the merger between Chrysler and Daimler-Benz
was the enormous difference between the two companies both in
the level of executive compensation and in the compensation ratios
of the highest-paid and lowest-paid employees. In 1997, for example,
Robert Eaton, Chrysler’s chairman of the board, received total com-
pensation of about $10 million, over 200 times the average worker’s
pay and nearly as much as the total compensation paid to all ten
members of Daimler-Benz’s management board combined. Daimler-
Benz’s chairman, Jurgen Schrempp, was paid about one-tenth as
much as Eaton, making his compensation approximately twenty
times that of the average Daimler-Benz worker.
Thus, a major question in the merger was the form that the
combined entity’s compensation structure should take. Schrempp
pointed out that the existing pay differences reflected cultural dif-
ferences, particularly the somewhat more egalitarian corporate cul-
ture in Germany, as demonstrated by labor representation on super-
visory boards. He also predicted that the U.S. model would prove to
be the proper form for DaimlerChrysler and other transnational
companies, except that “the only way to make big pay packets so-
cially acceptable is by linking them closely to performance.”6
Schrempp’s statement mirrors the rhetoric of corporate America.
Given that the other differences in corporate governance between
Germany and the United States are more nuanced and subtle than
is generally understood, you have to wonder if this was Schrempp’s
main point when he said that DaimlerChrysler created “the first
German company with a North American culture.” Any doubt was
cleared up when Schrempp subsequently proselytized for American-
style executive options at DaimlerChrysler’s April 2000 shareholder
meeting, something his German shareholders sensibly resisted.

Stock Options

A decade ago corporate governance mavens urged boards to pay
managers more in stoc kthan in cash to promote an alignment of
interests between managers and shareholders. The response was tre-


Directors at Work 209

mendous, a bit like the apocryphal story of Lady Astor’s famous quip
on the Titanic: “I asked for ice, but this is ridiculous.”
What the governance gurus got was a proliferation of payment
not in stoc kthat was the functional equivalent of the forgone cash
but instead stoc koptions with a value vastly exceeding what the cash
payment could reasonably have been. The explosion of option-based
compensation remains one of the most controversial subjects in cor-
porate governance history.
Some say that the widespread use of stoc koptions in the United
States simply reflects the priority given to this alignment goal in the
United States and that its relative infrequency in Europe and else-
where reflects the absence or irrelevance of this goal. However, the
tal kof alignment is more myth than truth and too often represents
an attempt to sanitize management compensation packages that con-
flict with shareholder interests (not to mention labor interests).

Stock Option Myths

No evidence indicates that the prevailing structure of executive com-
pensation in the United States comes anywhere close to aligning
manager and shareholder interests. On the contrary, a great deal of
evidence demonstrates that the compensation structure is random.
Many corporations give their managers stoc koptions which in-
crease in value simply through earnings retention, rather than be-
cause of improved performance resulting from superior deployment
of capital. By retaining and reinvesting net income, managers can
report annual earnings increases without doing anything to improve
real returns on capital.
Buffett makes the point: “You can get the same result personally
while operating from your rocking chair. Just quadruple the capital
you commit to a savings account and you will quadruple your earn-
ings. You would hardly expect hosannas for that particular accom-
plishment.”7
When that happens, stoc koptions rob the corporation and its
shareholders of wealth and allocate the booty to the optionees. In-
deed, once granted, stoc koptions are often irrevocable and uncon-
ditional and benefit the grantees without regard to individual per-
formance—a form of instant robbery.
Even if stoc koptions encourage optionees to thin kas share-
holders would, optionees are not exposed to the same downside risks
as shareholders are. If economic performance improves and the


210 In Managers We Trust

stoc kprice rises above the exercise price, the optionees will exercise
the option and share in the increase with shareholders. But if eco-
nomic performance is unfavorable and the stoc kprice remains below
the exercise price, optionees simply will not exercise the option.
Shareholders suffer from the corporation’s unfavorable performance,
but an option holder does not.
These awards also exacerbate the misalignment of interests be-
tween corporate option holders (usually senior executives) and other
workers. The awards dramatically increase the compensation differ-
ential between highly paid executives and ordinary laborers, a ratio
which is significantly higher in the United States than it is in Europe
and elsewhere. Accordingly, when stoc koptions are used, they
should be spread throughout the employee base—as GE has done—
rather than limited to the top dogs.

Stock Option Costs

The direct cost to shareholders of stoc koption compensation is the
dilution of their ownership interest. A common managerial response
to the dilution is to buy bac koutstanding shares. The trouble with
that solution is that it devours corporate funds that might be more
profitably deployed.
Shocking indirect costs are accounting rules that fail to require
employee stoc koptions to be recorded as an expense on the income
statement.8 This translates into earnings per share figures that over-
state actual earnings for companies with executive stoc koptions out-
standing. Even the diluted earnings per share figure does not reflect
these costs.
Accordingly, you must adjust earnings figures for the cost of op-
tions. Doing this is not easy, however, for not all information is nec-
essarily found in the financial statements. You need to examine the
footnotes for something called overhang, which is the percentage of
the company that outstanding stoc koptions would represent if they
were exercised. The average percentage has mushroomed from under
10% a few years ago to nearly 15% now.
Still, the actual cost of options is not presented directly, though
there is some footnote disclosure about this. The real cost equals
the price at the time of exercise minus the amount the executive
pays (the exercise price). This is the truest measure of cost because
the company could have generated that much by selling the optioned
shares to others at the prevalent price instead of at the option price.
The cost of executive stoc koptions is substantial, averaging


Directors at Work 211

about 5% of annual earnings among S&P 500 companies and in
some cases amounting to half of reported earnings, including at Ya-
hoo!, Polaroid, and Palm.9 In less dramatic but still striking exam-
ples, if stoc koptions were recorded as a cost, the 1999 earnings of
some major companies would be slashed: Cisco, 24%; Microsoft,
12%; IBM, 8%; and Oracle, 16%.10
These cost effects extend for many years, depending on the life
of the options. At many companies, options have a life of five years.
Increasingly, companies extend their lives to as long as 10 and 15
years.

Accountability

Legal rules are ill equipped to police executive compensation. The
general stance of U.S. courts is to evaluate compensation issues, if
at all, under a waste standard. This standard rarely upsets corporate
decisions. Waste requires pretty much the irrational trashing of cor-
porate assets in ways akin to dumping truckloads of cash into the
Hudson River. In the case of executive compensation, U.S. courts
are quite deferential to management indeed.
As for securities disclosure laws, the SEC requires substantial
and focused disclosure of top executive compensation in compara-
tive performance charts. Nevertheless, corporations continue to
structure executive compensation packages so that they don’t show
up in the bottom-line numbers. For example, after accounting stan-
dard setters ruled that a reduction in the exercise price of a previ-
ously issued option had to be recorded as an expense on the income
statement, many companies chose instead to extend the life of the
option.
Without effective legal or accounting regulations, the chief job
of policing executive compensation lies with the corporate board.
Board members must insist that executive compensation peg indi-
vidual contributions to corporate performance. Measuring executive
performance by business profitability is the most definitive yardstic
with regard to shareholder as well as labor interests. When measur-
ing performance, companies should reduce earnings by the capital
employed in the relevant business or by the earnings the firm retains.

Caveat

While Warren Buffett tends to share these criticisms of stoc koption
compensation packages, he is careful to record the following caveat:


212 In Managers We Trust

Some managers whom I admire enormously—and whose oper-
ating records are far better than mine—disagree with me re-
garding fixed-price options. They have built corporate cultures
that work, and fixed-price options have been a tool that helped
them. By their leadership and example, and by the use of options
as incentives, these managers have taught their colleagues to
thin klike owners. Such a culture is rare and when it exists
should perhaps be left intact—despite inefficiencies and ineq-
uities that may infest the option program.11

Investors should loo kfor boards that take the lead in policing
stoc koption compensation, but beware—they are scarce.

DEALS

Just as the disease of random executive compensation must be
avoided by intelligent investors and trustworthy boards, so must the
costs of imprudent acquisition policies and defensive tactics.

Offensive

Offensive acquisition strategies require careful board attention be-
cause of the strong possibility that even outstanding senior managers
possess individual interests that conflict with owner interests. Ac-
quisitions give CEOs enormous psychological benefits by expanding
their dominion and generating more action. Acquisitions driven by
these sorts of impulses come at shareholder expense.
Most acquisitions do not achieve gains in business value. A 1999
study by the global accounting firm KPMG concluded that “83% of
mergers [during the period 1996–1998, when trillions had been paid
in merger deals] failed to produce any benefits for shareholders and,
even more alarming, over half actually destroyed value.” That study
also found, based on interviews with managers involved in mergers,
that less than half did any postdeal review to test whether value was
added or subtracted!12
A governance problem exists because most acquisition attempts
do not come to the board for discussion until the process is sub-
stantially under way and until after the CEO has invested substantial
personal capital in them. Rejecting an acquisition proposal after the
CEO invests substantial personal capital is often considered a rejec-
tion of the CEO who presented the proposal to the board. This prob-
lem is especially acute among CEOs who resent hearing bad news.


Directors at Work 213

Cascades of stupid acquisitions come pouring in, often drowning the
board’s better judgment.
These timing problems make it difficult to design a governance
mechanism that would alleviate this pressure on the board. The ego
problems are just as intractable, as another Buffettism suggests:
“While deals often fail in practice, they never fail in projections—if
the CEO is visibly panting over a prospective acquisition, subordi-
nates and consultants will supply the requisite projections to ration-
alize any price.”13
Mattel, for example, is a worldwide leader in the design, man-
ufacture, and distribution of toys. In May 1999 it bought the Learn-
ing Company, a producer of educational software for personal com-
puters. Mattel paid for the $3.8 billion purchase by using Mattel
stoc kat a time when the stoc kwas trading at about $26 a share
(down already from an average trading price over the prior year of
around $40). Mattel’s chair, Jill Barad, announced in July 1999 that
the Learning Company was contributing to Mattel’s overall opera-
tions with “exceptionally strong growth” in revenues and margins and
said this “was one of the reasons this merger made so much sense
for Mattel.”14
Barad did not say how the computer software business related
to Mattel’s traditional products, such as Barbie dolls, Fisher-Price
toys, and Hot Wheels. But just three months later, in October
1999, Mattel announced that the Learning Company division’s rev-
enues had declined and it had lost money because of, among other
things, higher than expected product returns from customers and
write-offs of bad debts.15 Instead of earning $50 million that quar-
ter as Barad estimated, it lost over $100 million, and Mattel’s stoc
plummeted to about $11 a share. Many analysts, at least in hind-
sight, reported that these problems at the Learning Company were
not new and should have been uncovered and discounted before
Mattel bought it.
These analysts also thought that Mattel fit the description of a
company about to make a bad acquisition. If sales growth in your
core business is declining and you can’t seem to do anything about
it through product, marketing, or distribution improvements, one
impulse is to buy yourself some growth through an acquisition. Mat-
tel’s sales growth, incidentally, was declining in its core products
right before the Learning Company acquisition. So too, for that mat-
ter, was the Learning Company’s. (Mattel’s board ousted Barad in
early 2000, awarding her an exorbitant severance package, and re-
placed her with Kraft Foods CEO Robert Eckert.)


214 In Managers We Trust

Contrast Mattel’s story with the policies of Disney. Disney’s
philosophy is to make only acquisitions that are in a related or
complementary field that current management understands fully,
and at a fair price. In its most important acquisition, Capital Cities
ABC fit the bill. Disney’s long-time chairman, Michael Eisner, had
worked at ABC from 1966 through 1976 and had seen it grow from
a networ kcritics called the “fourth of three” to first place in every
category.
After Capital Cities bought ABC in 1986, Tom Murphy and Dan
Burke catapulted it to yet new heights, and the combination with
Disney made sense. Walt Disney himself liked ABC as well. After
all, ABC helped finance Disneyland in 1955, and Walt brought ABC
to Hollywood when he began what is now The Wonderful World of
Disney. Disney’s Internet business benefited enormously from the
addition of ABC.com, ESPN.com, and a host of cable assets that
enable important growth opportunities.

Defensive

Takeover defenses are the flip side of offensive acquisition strategies.
Antitakeover devices such as the poison pill protect management’s
decision making by discouraging attempts to acquire the corporation
or remove incumbent directors (as AMP’s defense against Allied-
Signal attests). If some or a majority of stockholders deem a takeover
attempt to be in the corporation’s and their best interest and the
potential acquirer is willing to pay a premium over the prevailing
market price or intrinsic value of the corporation’s common stock,
antitakeover devices wor kagainst shareholders.
Disney’s acquisition philosophy is also illustrative on this side of
the table. Corporate raiders of the early 1980s sought to acquire
Disney and bust it up but Roy Disney would not let that happen.
He preserved Disney as a great American institution and facilitated
a recommitment to the fundamental businesses that had made it
great. Disney animation, for example, with Roy at the helm, rein-
vented itself and surged with a long series of critically and popularly
acclaimed films. In doing so, Disney adopted the best takeover de-
fense strategy there is: an extraordinary business. (More on Disney
in the next chapter.)
To be sure, situations exist in which hostile offers are inadequate
and not in the interests of the corporation or any of its constituents.
Yet incumbent managers facing unwanted takeover talks naturally


Directors at Work 215

will resist the efforts of the acquiring firm whether or not their re-
sistance best serves the corporation. After all, in most cases their
jobs are at risk.
Within U.S. corporations—and probably increasingly within cor-
porations organized elsewhere—takeovers put unmatured stoc kop-
tions at risk. Faced with this prospect, managers may employ mech-
anisms designed to resist inferior bids in an effort to resist superior
bids. They thus may use a poison pill against a bid that is great for
shareholders when it should be used only to deter bids that are bad
for shareholders.
In these situations, boards must recognize that CEOs and their
troops are under fire, just as they are when a board challenges one
of their proposed offensive acquisitions.
In both situations boards should expect managers to adopt a
siege mentality which obscures honest thinking about what is in the
owners’ interests. In both offensive and defensive situations there is
no clear mechanism that can assure that boards will respond prop-
erly, but boards must at least recognize what is happening psycho-
logically in these situations if they hope to respond effectively at all.
For investors, identifying directors with that capacity is key.

CAPITAL

A company generating substantial amounts of excess cash can deploy
it in one of four ways. It can reinvest in the business, repurchase its
own shares, distribute the cash in dividends to shareholders, and, as
was just noted, make acquisitions.
Aside from a few formal and manipulable limits, U.S. law gives
boards of directors unbridled discretion in the choice of these uses,
including declaring and paying dividends and making or not making
repurchases. Corporate charters rarely restrict dividend policies, al-
though a corporation’s loan and credit agreements sometimes do.
The policy of most U.S. boards is to pay regular quarterly cash
dividends at a stable or steadily increasing dollar amount. This pat-
tern is inconsistent with the reality that underlying business perfor-
mance is hardly ever that smooth. Earnings are almost always bumpy
(even if less bumpy than average stoc kprices).
Dividends tend to be way higher than they should be. Given the
importance of dividend policy in capital allocation decisions, certain
common reasons that boards use to justify their policies, such as


216 In Managers We Trust

signaling confidence and giving the appearance of reliability, are ei-
ther strange or disingenuous.
We should give credit to boards that use a more rigorous ap-
proach for setting dividend policy, an ideal set forth by Warren Buf-
fett. The test distinguishes between restricted earnings, those which
must be reinvested in a business just to maintain its competitive
position, and unrestricted earnings, which should be retained only
when there is a reasonable prospect that for every dollar retained,
at least one dollar of market value will be created for shareholders;
otherwise, the dollar of earnings should be paid out.16 Microsoft fol-
lows this policy pretty well, never having paid a dividend and gen-
erating great returns on the reinvested capital.
Boards can justify retaining earnings under this test only if the
capital retained produces incremental earnings at least equal to the
return generally available to the shareholders. For companies that
can reinvest earnings in this manner, dividends should not be paid
and boards should ignore any negative signals this policy sends, such
as lac kof confidence or unreliability (though they should pay atten-
tion to the resulting tax advantages to shareholders).
The smartest thing a company can do with undervalued stoc kis
to buy it back. Obviously, if a stoc kis selling in the market at half
its intrinsic value, the company can buy $2 in value by paying $1 in
cash. You rarely find better uses of capital than that. Stoc krepur-
chases usually give a stockholder a slight tax advantage. Dividends
on common stoc kare taxed as ordinary income at rates as high as
39.6%, whereas income generated by the repurchase of stoc kheld
longer than a year is treated as capital gains at rates no higher than
20%.
Stoc kbuybacks are not always what they seem. They reduce the
number of a company’s shares outstanding, thus increasing earnings
per share. The typical result is that investors buy more of that stoc
and thus bid the price up, mistakenly believing that the repurchases
are a managerial signal that the company’s stoc kis underpriced. Of-
ten, however, the repurchase program is a cognate of a stoc kissu-
ance program to offset shares issued upon the exercise of stoc kop-
tions. The increased stoc kprice, after all, means increasing the value
of stoc koptions on that stock. When a repurchase program and an
issuance program are run simultaneously, you should be more dis-
criminating in your judgment of what management is doing.
It is possible that this effect could lead management (with many
stoc koptions at its feet) to prefer buybacks even if that were not


Directors at Work 217

the smartest way to allocate the company’s capital. Indeed, options
create incentives to borrow money for stoc krepurchases that boost
earnings per share and return on equity. That poses a major risk, as
a smaller equity base in a crisis can push a company closer to bank-
ruptcy, severely damaging shareholder interests (as well as the inter-
ests of others).
In contrast to the occasional wisdom of stoc krepurchases is the
universal folly of stoc ksplits. Stoc ksplits have three consequences,
none of them beneficial to the stockholders. They increase trans-
action costs by promoting high share turnover; they attract share-
holders with short-term, market-oriented views who unduly focus on
stoc kmarket prices; and, as a result of both of those effects, they
lead to prices that depart materially from intrinsic business value.
With no offsetting benefits, splitting a stoc kis nonsense. Nev-
ertheless, most companies do it, including GE, Microsoft, and Am-
azon.com. Berkshire Hathaway is one of the handful that don’t. After
going public in mid-1997, Amazon.com split its stoc kthree times
from June 1998 to September 1999! GE split its stoc konly nine times
in its hundred-plus-year history, though three of those splits oc-
curred in the last six years of the 1990s.
The only meritorious argument favoring stoc ksplits is that they
reduce the per share price of stoc kand thus enable a wider investor
group to participate. If no U.S. company in history had ever split its
stock, the per share price of some of the best companies would be
in the tens of thousands of dollars (as is the case at Berkshire Hath-
away, for example). That price level is prohibitive for many investors.
This argument does not justify the high frequency of stoc ksplits,
however, which are used to keep prices below a couple of hundred
dollars—an amount that is affordable by all investors.

CHECKING UP

As Chapter 10 showed, for accounting information to be valuable,
users must have justifiable confidence in its integrity. Forces that
jeopardize integrity are often intractable: Business innovation, evo-
lution, and complexity, coupled with the formal nature of accounting
rules inevitably create a substantial zone of managerial discretion in
financial reporting.
Integrity in financial reporting is promoted through internal con-
trol systems and by external auditor certifications, both of which can


218 In Managers We Trust

constrain managerial discretion somewhat. For these mechanisms to
be effective, however, the board of directors must assure that both
internal controls and external audits do this.
Internal financial reporting controls are designed to assure that
transactions are executed in accordance with management policy
and are recorded properly in the accounting records (and to assure
that assets are deployed only in accordance with management pol-
icy). They range from daily journal entries that are reviewed regularly
by others, to periodic taking of inventory, to procedures for review
of judgments concerning depreciation, to the articulation and review
of ris kmanagement policies. Some of these tools are required by
federal securities laws.
Within a corporation, both the board of directors and the man-
agers play a role in defining, implementing, and evaluating internal
controls. In principle, however, the chief and ultimate responsibility
for internal controls rests with the board of directors, both as a mat-
ter of common sense and as a matter of policy. Boards have a com-
parative informational advantage and greater motivation to police
managerial opportunism than managers do. This obligation entails
supervising the design of internal control systems and supporting
their administration.
The critical importance of internal controls to the integrity of
financial reporting is evidenced by the requirement that outside au-
ditors review them in connection with annual audits of a company’s
financial statements. This audit is intended to obtain objective as-
surance that the financial statements are relevant and reliable, based
on a general review of the financial statements and the underlying
day-to-day records and periodic summaries on which they are based.
The audit is a monitoring mechanism that lends credibility to
the financial statements. For that credibility to be meaningful, how-
ever, the auditor must wor kclosely with members of the board of
directors, and both the auditor and those directors must act with
diligence, independence, and awareness. Several challenges are
posed for a board and its audit committee.
First, an audit conducted by an independent firm does not
change the fact that a company’s management prepares the financial
statements and is responsible for them. The audit is a review of those
statements. The audit does not entail a review of every financial
transaction in which the company engaged during the period covered
by the financial statements. That is a practical impossibility for any
auditor and even more so for any audit committee. Businesses en-


Directors at Work 219

gage in huge numbers of financial transactions during the course of
the typical financial period, usually one year. Instead, audits are con-
ducted on a “test basis” by reviewing a sample of the hundreds or
thousands of transactions of a variety of kinds engaged in by the firm
over time.
Second, with respect to the detection of fraud, neither the au-
ditor nor the audit committee is always in a position to root it out.
This is the case principally because it is impossible for the audit to
include an examination of every single transaction in which a com-
pany engaged or in which management says it engaged.
Third, the auditor must be independent of the company, a re-
quirement imposed by the canons of professional responsibility of
the auditing profession; so too must the members of the audit com-
mittee, a requirement of stoc kexchange rules endorsed by the SEC.
Audits lacking impartial and objective professional judgment fail to
promote financial reporting integrity. At best, they end up function-
ing as merely another type of internal control.
Audits are harmful if they carry a false appearance of indepen-
dent certification that induces undue reliance. Also, since effective
independent audits include testing internal controls, the integrity of
those systems is undermined by a nonobjective and potentially bi-
ased audit that diminishes rather than enhances overall integrity.
Audit firm independence is a hot topic. The big global auditing
firms have expanded their businesses beyond the traditional audit
function to include consulting and other practices that could in
some circumstances compromise their ability to contribute integrity
to financial reporting. These firms have merged, restructured, or
been acquired by other corporations. Their clients and business are
evolving into more sophisticated, technologically advanced, and
transnational operations.
The SEC established the Independence Standards Board (ISB)
to address auditor independence issues,17 but it remains a principal
responsibility of the board of directors and its audit committee to
assure an independent financial review. Those in charge are account-
able for adopting a diligent and alert mind-set that lets them rigor-
ously assess the company’s internal controls, the testing of its
reported accounts, and the likelihood that what they see account-
ingwise is what really happened businesswise.
The audit committee is the one place where independent direc-
tors are called for, but independence is not as essential as expertise
in accounting and/or auditing, as the new stoc kexchange rules now


220 In Managers We Trust

require. That is a crucial step (though by no means a sufficient one)
in giving assurance that, in the words of the traditional SEC stan-
dard, “a reasonable investor, knowing all relevant facts and circum-
stances, would perceive an auditor as having neither mutual nor
conflicting interests with its audit client and as exercising objective
and impartial judgment on all issues brought to the auditor’s atten-
tion.”
Only then are financial statements worth analyzing. Auditing is
an area over which the board of directors must take control and
provide leadership. Boards that consistently do this deserve credit.
Those which do not should be penalized—and they should be pe-
nalized long before the outside auditor gets around to blowing the
whistle, as shareholders of Rite-Aid discovered to their chagrin and
loss in late 1999, when its outside auditors resigned from their audit
engagement on the grounds that they could no longer trust man-
agement to tell them the truth!

Important as the auditor, audit committee, and board are in their
key jobs, there remains one person holding the torch for investors—
the CEO. Buffett says:

The term “earnings” has a precise ring to it. And when an earn-
ings figure is accompanied by an unqualified auditor’s certifi-
cate, a naive reader might thin kit comparable in certitude to ?,
calculated to dozens of decimal places.
In reality, however, earnings can be as pliable as putty when
a charlatan heads the company reporting them. Eventually truth
will surface, but in the meantime a lot of money can change
hands. Indeed, some important American fortunes have been
created by the monetization of accounting mirages.18

Avoiding charlatans is even more important than identifying ex-
cellent boards, so let’s move on to the corner suite.


C h a p t e r 1 4

THE FIRESIDE CEO

he legendary investor Phil Fisher described his scuttlebutt ap-
Tproach to investing as requiring diligent investigation of man-
agement. He boldly interviewed a company’s customers, suppliers,
and employees about the managers and also spoke to management
directly. The Fisher method is followed today by venture capitalists
but is prohibitive for most average investors, who cannot get out and
visit those folks or even tal kto them.
Some reasonable substitutes are available, though. You can listen
in on the investor conference calls held by most companies on a
quarterly basis and chaired by the CEO (the dial-in numbers for
these calls are available from the company and from most brokerage
firms). You can also attend the periodic “road shows” that companies
take through your locality; they are particularly worthwhile when the
CEO is in tow (which isn’t always the case) and you can attend
annual meetings to get a bird’s-eye view of the chief. These and other
events are often available on the Internet as Webcasts.
You can also read the voluminous material written about the
CEOs of most companies and by the CEOs themselves. At the top
of the reading list for insight into the character and business ori-
entation of a CEO is his annual letters to shareholders. Most of
these are public relations documents, ghostwritten, stylized, and full
of puffery. No one is fooled by messages written in the promotions
department, but among the glossy, photograph-laden, chart-strewn
marketing materials are a handful of letters actually written by the
CEO. Those are the letters worth reading.

MASTER SERVANTS

The seven basic characteristics most widely cited by venture capi-
talists as important to loo kfor in managers are integrity, achieve-

221

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


222 In Managers We Trust

ment, energy, intelligence, knowledge, leadership, and creativity.1
Which of these is the most important?
Obviously, you want to avoid entrusting your wealth to a brilliant
croo kor a trustworthy idiot. An above-average IQ and these other
traits are certainly assets, but your CEO need not be in the top 10%
in the world on all these scales (who is?).
You might be tempted to follow the line of Fred Schwed in Where
Are the Customers’ Yachts? who joked that he’d prefer a smart crim-
inal to an honest bonehead because at least with a writ and a cop
he’d collect from the thief whereas all he’d get from the bonehead
was a pathetic apology. Don’t do this.
Buffett repeatedly emphasizes that the one characteristic that
belongs on a pedestal is integrity. This means a CEO who thinks of
your interests first, one who has what Buffett calls an owner orien-
tation. CEOs reveal the degree of their owner orientation in their let-
ters, as described by the rules Warren Buffett sets for himself when
he writes his annual letter to Berkshire Hathaway shareholders: “to
tell you the business facts that we would want to know if our posi-
tions were reversed. We owe you no less. . . . The CEO who misleads
others in public may eventually mislead himself in private.”2 Apply
that standard in evaluating whether a CEO deserves your trust.
Everyone knows that Warren Buffett is an enormously successful
investor, but not everyone is aware that he is also an enormously
successful and owner-oriented manager. On this score, Buffett is to
business management what Ted Williams was to baseball. Both are
in classes by themselves, Ted constantly hitting near .400 and War-
ren constantly writing lucid and candid reports of his successes and
failures at Berkshire Hathaway (compiled into the boo The Essays
of Warren Buffett: Lessons for Corporate America).
While Buffett is in a class by himself, there are many runners-
up, and searching for them by reading CEO letters is a valuable and
often entertaining investing exercise. This chapter looks at what is
revealed by the letters of three leaders who display not only honesty,
the key characteristic you should see kin a CEO, but also in various
degrees achievement, energy, intelligence, knowledge, leadership,
and creativity.

ACTION

Few CEOs have affected corporate America as GE’s Jac kWelch has.3
By word and action since taking the helm at General Electric in


The Fireside CEO 223

1979, Welch has redefined major aspects of business management.
In his widely followed annual letters to GE shareholders, Welch ar-
ticulates a creative set of core operating elements and explains how
their practical applications produce a new kind of company that ex-
ploits the vast resources of a large organization with the passion and
hunger usually associated with smaller companies, all within a cor-
porate culture committed to cultivating the best practices.
GE is one of the largest companies in the world. Welch trans-
formed it from a widely diverse set of 350 businesses and major
product lines into what he calls an “integrated, diversified company.”
Welch determined that GE’s strength from diversity could be real
only if each business was number one or two in its particular market.
Through a policy of “fixing, selling, or closing” businesses that
weren’t, Welch led GE to occupy a leadership position in the dozen
businesses it now operates. Those businesses are integrated as an
overall company through a boundaryless culture united by a shared
thirst for better ideas to wor kfaster and reach higher.
GE shareholders benefited enormously from this culture of
boundaryless and integrated diversity, enjoying average annual re-
turns on equity exceeding 24% during Welch’s stewardship. Hun-
dreds of thousands of GE employees also benefited through an en-
hanced system of internal rewards and recognition that encourages
involvement. A large number of GE alumni moved on to lead other
businesses, including Larry Bossidy, former CEO of AlliedSignal and
coauthor with Welch of a number of his letters.
Ideas generated or adapted at GE were celebrated among other
businesses and leaders, for the concept of boundarylessness is taken
so literally at GE that it shares its ideas the world over. As Welch
notes, a key GE value is to treat resource allocation as a dynamic
process: “Sometimes a business benefits as a net importer of dol-
lars, ideas and talent while at other times the same business will be
called upon to be a net exporter for the benefit of the Company as
a whole.”
Accolades for GE flowed during Welch’s stewardship. Fortune
magazine named GE its “Most Admired Company in America” in
1998 and 1999, and The Financial Times named it “the World’s Most
Respected Company” in those two years. Time magazine upped the
ante, calling GE “the Company of the Century,” and a 1999 Business
Week survey said that GE boasted the best board of directors. As
Welch said in his 1999 letter, Thomas Edison would be pleased with
the company he founded over a century ago.
Welch’s letters not only contain a firsthand account of the de-


224 In Managers We Trust

velopment of GE’s unique culture but also reflect Welch’s imagi-
nation, energy, and vision. They are a concrete exposition of the
values that pervade GE’s culture, how those values are implemented,
their fruits, and the qualities of leadership that make it all possible—
a great resource for the sophisticated investor as well as the intel-
ligent manager.

The Core Operating Elements

Welch envisions an organization without boundaries. Artificial walls
dividing parts of the inside of an organization are to be destroyed.
The entire enterprise is a team, and responsibility is shared. A cul-
ture without boundaries renders impossible excuses such as “not
invented here,” a common way to evade responsibility. In this cul-
ture, Welch created “a vast laboratory whose principal product is new
ideas.” Ideas generated in one place are transported to others.
External boundaries are also exploded in this corporate culture.
Employees engage with broader communities through volunteer
work, and the company participates in outreach programs. GE en-
gages its various constituents as part of its daily life, learning how
better to serve customers as well as coventurers, distributors, and
others. GE is happy to learn from its own but equally happy to adapt
ideas created by others, including suppliers and competitors.
Boundaries retard development, stifle creativity, and complicate
operations. Destroying boundaries enabled GE to flourish amid
Welch’s three other core operating elements: speed, stretch, and sim-
plification.
Speed thrives on change. Teamwor kenhances speed, enabling
substantial increases in measures of performance straight across a
business. For example, by diminishing the cycle from order to re-
mittance, speed enhances inventory turnover. For a company GE’s
size, every single-digit improvement in its inventory turnover pro-
duces over a billion dollars in free cash for investment.
Speed’s “fun and excitement” facilitates stretch, the idea of al-
ways setting outsized goals. The stretch philosophy says that if you
thin kyou can increase inventory turnover by one point in the next
cycle, set your goal at increasing it by two points. A boundaryless
culture is the key to a successful stretch philosophy because it em-
phasizes that “the quality of effort toward achieving the ‘impossible’
is the ultimate measure” of performance.
Stretch reverses much of conventional practice and incentive


The Fireside CEO 225

structures in business. At many businesses, managers set targets and
are evaluated on the basis of whether they meet them. The incentive
is to set modest targets. In a stretch setting managers are encouraged
to set extraordinarily ambitious goals and are then evaluated accord-
ing to how they did in one period compared to how they did in the
prior period. In short, “performance is measured against how the
world turned out to be—how well a business anticipated change and
dealt with it—rather than against some ‘plan’ or internal number
negotiated a year earlier.”
Speed and stretch are complemented by the final core operating
element of a boundaryless environment: simplification. Complexity,
whether in business organization charts, communications, or goal
setting, impairs speed and stretch and is foreign to a boundaryless
culture. Simplicity breeds self-confidence, which is conveyed
through direct plans and straightforward speech, setting “big, clear
targets.” The clarity arising from simplicity has another big virtue:
It enhances speed. As Welch says, “simple messages travel faster,
simpler designs reach the market faster, and the elimination of clut-
ter allows faster decision making.”

The Implementing Practices

GE implements its core operating elements of speed, stretch, and
simplification to realize the fruits of these elements. The key to pro-
ducing those fruits is the concept of integrated diversity. It is the
strength a company generates from being number one or number
two in all its businesses and drawing on the resources of each busi-
ness to sustain or enhance its position in others.
Two steps were necessary to achieve integrated diversity at GE.
The first was to keep only the businesses that were number one or
two in their particular markets. Each business needs to be strong in
its own right. Then the collection of businesses produces “a critical
mass of competitive advantage.” To exploit that competitive advan-
tage in turn requires delayering the management structure, which
Welch achieved by dismantling the multiple layers of management
that had clogged the company in the earlier era. Delayering en-
hanced productivity, making the aggregate of the parts far more pow-
erful than their mere sum.
Through a strategy called “Work-Out,” Welch sought and got
input from everyone in the company (and some people outside it).
Long before Perot and Clinton repopularized the town meeting con-


226 In Managers We Trust

cept in American politics, GE practiced it, getting ideas from those
closest to the particular problem. This technique not only is most
likely to generate the best solutions, it also builds self-confidence
through participation and counters insecurity by discouraging turf
battles, parochialism, and other impediments to speed and stretch.
Apart from these practices within the boundaryless culture,
Welch instilled a sense of the right sorts of managers for a thriving
enterprise. Four types of managers are defined. The first two are
easy: Type I believes in GE’s values and delivers (and sticks around),
whereas type II does neither (and doesn’t last long). Type III is a
believer but an erratic deliverer and usually gets another chance.
Type IV is the trickiest: He or she delivers short-term results but
does not believe in GE’s values. Instead of living and breathing boun-
daryless values and energizing and exciting people to new heights of
creativity and productivity, this manager controls, oppresses, intim-
idates, and squeezes people. Welch solved the type IV case by ele-
vating shared values above short-term results, and so these types
don’t last long at GE either.
GE’s system of rewards and recognition glues these managerial
qualities to GE’s values by reinforcing its boundaryless and speed/
stretch culture. Under Welch’s stewardship at GE, the number of
employees eligible for stoc koptions soared from 400 to nearly
30,000. Speakers at big company meetings are selected not by their
title or ran kbut on the basis of “what people know that can be
shared, borrowed, and expanded on.”
Finally, GE’s “360 degree” management appraisal calls for man-
agers to be evaluated not only by their superiors but also by
the people who wor kunder and alongside them. This evaluation
focuses GE’s leaders “on finding and rewarding people who dem-
onstrated an ability to get every mind in the organization into the
relentless search for ideas.”

Fruits of the Culture

Concrete results of the core operating elements implemented
through a strategy of integrated diversity and Work-Out include
those generated at GE’s Crotonville Institute management school
and those originating on shop floors throughout the company. Best
practices has become a model emulated throughout the world and
is a hallmar kof Welch’s GE. Crotonville is a wellspring of thought
on management and business, producing great ideas for decades and


The Fireside CEO 227

sharing them not only with GE businesses but with businesspeople
the world over.
Welch notes that “the intellectual underpinning of Work-Out
consists of ideas like worker involvement, trust and empowerment—
shopworn and even platitudinous concepts.” Yet he goes on to say
that at GE, “the difference is that our whole organization is, in fact,
living them, every day.” GE wields these “soft concepts” as real com-
petitive weapons in victorious battles, not merely “inscribing them
on coffee mugs and T-shirts.”
Crotonville, as Welch describes it, combines the “thirst for learn-
ing of academia with an action environment usually seen only in
small, hungry companies.” Animating GE’s culture of ideas is a mode
of thought linked to the core operating elements of speed and stretch
called bullet-train thinking. Originated by the CEO of Yokogawa, this
metaphor signifies that if you want to increase a train’s speed by 10
mph, tinker with its horsepower; if you want to double it, brea kout
of conventional thinking and goal setting.
The fruits of the learning culture reinforce the core operating
elements by producing additional mechanisms. Consider two big
ideas embraced at GE that also exhibit the speed and stretch phi-
losophy. Co-location, Welch says, is the “ultimate boundaryless be-
havior.” As “unsophisticated as can be,” it means conducting all the
functions for a product in one room without walls. All project par-
ticipants are simultaneously involved, including at the design stages
people from manufacturing and marketing as well as suppliers and
customers. Quick response is a cycle-time reduction technique that
similarly erases barriers between functions for a product. With co-
location, it vastly reduces average inventory and proportionately bol-
sters inventory turnover.
Other fruits of this learning culture taken from outside GE help
implement the core operating elements. Demand Flow Technology
was borrowed from the GE customer American Standard to multiply
inventory turnover and move toward GE’s goal noted in an earlier
chapter of zero working capital. Quick Market Intelligence (QMI), a
strategy adapted from Wal-Mart to get direct customer feedbac
weekly, “employs out-of-the-box thinking and cross-functional teams
dedicated to removing obstacles to cost reduction.” The Toshiba-
originated idea of Half Movement, another variation on the speed-
stretch operating elements, envisions each product being produced
with half the parts and half the weight in half the time.
Six Sigma quality is perhaps the most famous concept Welch


228 In Managers We Trust

pioneered at GE. It means “the virtual elimination of defects from
every product, process and transaction [GE] engages in every day
around the globe.” It is not just a slogan but a measurement: It
means “fewer than 3.4 defects per million operations in a manufac-
turing or service process.” That is nearly perfect quality when you
consider that average sigma quality in corporate America is around
3 or 4, at a cost of about 10 to 15% of corporate revenues, Welch
reports.
Led by experts on quality who, depending on their skill level in
Six Sigma thinking, are creatively called Master Blac kBelts, Blac
Belts or Green Belts, the activity dissects every process to improve
key business concerns such as enhancing customer productivity and
reducing customer capital outlays while increasing the “quality,
speed and efficiency” of all GE operations.
Launched in 1995, Six Sigma quality spread “like wildfire”
throughout GE to generate substantial returns on the billion-plus
dollars invested in it. For example, Six Sigma contributed over $300
million to GE’s operating income in 1997, $750 million in 1998, and
about $2 billion in 1999, and the impact continues. Profit margins
at GE historically ran around 10%, but with Six Sigma they were
boosted to 15% to 17% and higher.
All this leads to what Welch hoped for all along: a new kind of
company that is a hybrid of typical large companies with vast re-
sources and typical small companies with insatiable appetites. Welch
denies that GE is a conglomerate in the usual sense of the word.
Welch’s model is very different. It calls for GE to reign only over
businesses where it is number one or number two, generate ideas
from those businesses, and spread them to the others, all in a culture
of energy, excitement, and creativity.
The learning culture created by Work-Out and boundarylessness
that fueled Six Sigma gains enabled GE to get into e-business far
more rapidly and with greater depth and breadth than pretty much
any company close to its size. GE generates billions in revenue from
its e-business, but Welch notes that the transformation it has
brought is more pervasive.
Tackling the question of why the Internet revolution began at
small start-ups rather than big resourceful companies such as GE,
Welch speculated that it was a mystery of the unknown. At GE,
however, it did not take long for people to overcome that e-fear
and digitize the entire company, a tas kWelch says was way easier
than anyone at the company had ever imagined. E-business was


The Fireside CEO 229

made for GE, he says, telling us that the “E” in GE assumes a
whole new meaning in this learning culture that rides out all great
new ideas.

Leadership

Creating, implementing, and harvesting best practices from a boun-
daryless culture built on speed, stretch, and simplification require
leadership. The cornerstone of successful leadership is recognizing
that people matter most in any organization. Welch repeatedly em-
phasizes this characteristic, which is the essence of Work-Out, the
bedroc kof best practices, and the sine qua non of superior man-
agement teams.
Leaders must constantly be on guard. They must take reality
checks and face the results. They must avoid the pervasive tempta-
tion to wish, hope, and temporize. Equally important, leaders must
encourage their troops to do the same. To ignite a mammoth com-
pany like GE with the energy of a small company requires “passion,
hunger, appetite for change, customer focus, and, above all, the
speed to see reality more clearly and to act on it faster.” Doing all
this, Welch concludes, requires leaders to foster a culture in which
everything “comes bac kto people—their ideas, their motivation,
their passion to win.”
Effective leaders share the same values as their troops. GE’s
enormous size and diversity are bound together through common
values. These valves include excellence measured in terms of cus-
tomer satisfaction, acceptance of change as a constant force, candid
communication in all directions, and acceptance of the paradox of
managing such an organization, which is simultaneously a single
entity and a collection of many different businesses.
Driving all GE’s initiatives are what Welch calls a “a unique
brand of 21st century business leader—the GE ‘A’ player.” These are
leaders with “a vision and the ability to articulate that vision to the
team, so vividly and powerfully that it also becomes their vision.”
They embody GE’s “4Es” of leadership—Energy, Energize-ability,
Edge, and Execution. In other words they embody enormous per-
sonal energy, the ability to energize others, “the instinct and the
courage to make tough calls decisively but with fairness and absolute
integrity,” and “the consistent ability to turn vision into results.” The
best A leaders, Welch concludes, are like the best coaches: They
insist on having only A players on the field.


230 In Managers We Trust

Welch developed a culture of creativity—one without the bar-
nacles of bureaucracy that retard progress—where it is possible to
blend the virtues of both large and small organizations. Boundary-
lessness is a “behavior definer” that gets people together as teams
with speed and drive. Work-Out epitomizes a process designed to
generate and capture good ideas whatever their origin. This culture
and these processes characterize the type of company GE has be-
come: a company of action, just like its leader.

LIGHTS

The Walt Disney Company is no Mickey Mouse operation, and CEO
Mike Eisner knows it.4 Eisner has one of the most enviable jobs in
the world, but he makes it loo keasier than it is. Since 1984 he has
run Disney as if he himself were Walt Disney—the ultimate owner
orientation. The animation, the characters, the films, the broadcast
TV, and now publishing and bigger theme parks keep Eisner on his
toes at this multi-billion-dollar entertainment company.
In his letters to shareholders, Eisner summarizes his views on
management and strategies for growth through times of change and
economic adversity. Direct commentary on specific aspects of Dis-
ney’s entertainment business—animation, characters, television,
Euro Disney, and the Internet—evinces qualities of trust as well as
creativity and leadership. Eisner discusses some of the special prob-
lems a large, exquisitely public company such as Disney confronts
as a business operated in the limelight of public opinion.

The More Things Change . . .

Eisner sums up his whole philosophy of business as follows: “call
meetings about subjects that really matter—and show up.” Parallel-
ing the situation at Welch’s GE, the big meetings at Disney are the
“synergy meetings” that bring together the heads and top managers
of each division to share ideas so that the best of one division can
be transplanted to the others. Motivated by Disney’s general devo-
tion to synergy and all the participants’ desire to impress their col-
leagues “with the breadth and creativity of their synergistic initia-
tives,” participants prepare hard for these gatherings, with
tremendous results.
The synergy meetings reflect an overall strategy at Disney an-


The Fireside CEO 231

chored on four guiding lights. First and foremost is the goal of in-
creasing shareholder wealth while simultaneously discharging re-
sponsibility to Disney’s employees and its communities in an ethical
manner. The second goal is “to increase productivity through supe-
rior work,” emphasizing that setting “the highest standards drives the
highest results.” The third goal is to “concentrate on continuing to
lead creatively,” and the fourth is a “strategic direction of quality and
innovation.”
These anchoring qualities are necessary to exploit the opportu-
nities and confront the challenges posed by constant change.
“Change is the engine of growth and the muse of creativity,” Eisner
says. It’s what makes things happen in life and at Disney. Eisner
addresses technological change with special lucidity. Soothsayers
regularly announce the edge of technology as spelling doom for cer-
tain industries, such as entertainment, in the face of advances such
as 500-channel television capability.
Eisner loves it, likening such predictions to those Walt faced
when TV first emerged and forecasters foretold the death of film.
Far from shutting down any aspects of Disney’s business, TV gave
Disney a new outlet for its products. For those who are creative and
driven, such technological and other changes mean opportunity, not
obsolescence.
Tough times must be dealt with when they come, of course, but
it is far better to deal with them before they come—in robust eco-
nomic times. Eisner thinks that way, and Disney’s business is orga-
nized that way. Although Eisner no longer likes the term “recession-
resistant” as a description of Disney, the account he gives of its
ability and strategy to make headway in tough economic times makes
the label apt.
The roaring economic climate of the 1980s led many companies
(and individuals) down shortsighted and treacherous paths, but not
Disney. It stayed clear of overpaying for businesses; didn’t acquire
what it didn’t need; kept its balance sheet clean, strong, and finan-
cially conservative; grew internally; preserved its franchise by nur-
turing its core values; and avoided teaming up with others who could
detract from the Disney brand.
Opportunities present themselves, of course, and even a conser-
vative company must be ready to exploit them. The fall of commu-
nism opened enormous new markets. Disney penetrated them
through Euro Disney and through television programming in former
Soviet bloc countries.


232 In Managers We Trust

Through adversity and opportunity, Eisner recounts how the
challenges he faces are not all that different from those Walt Disney
faced 50 or 60 years ago. The challenges listed in Disney’s annual
report of 1940 were eerily similar to its list in 1990: external world
crises such as war, studio expansion, film production expansion, for-
eign currency fluctuations, and control over the cost of creative tal-
ent. All these things remain, including, the pundits notwithstanding,
the ris kof war, which is hardly expected far in advance by the in-
vesting public.
Disney’s recession resistance comes from a combination of a
strong brand, financial conservatism, and a disciplined emphasis on
growth that concentrates mainly on internal expansion supple-
mented with selective expansion through prudent acquisition. Ex-
ternal expansion is prudent when it is necessary to preserve access
to the means of entertainment delivery, especially to the home en-
tertainment environment. That often entails expansion through tech-
nological advances, but Eisner cautions that he will not let Disney
invest in technology for its own sake.
Disney’s commitment must be to the content of the entertain-
ment, Eisner says, not its delivery mechanisms. He regards Marshall
McLuhan’s claim that “the medium is the message” as anachronistic,
maybe true when written but no longer the case in a world of pro-
liferating delivery systems—numerous broadcast networks, indepen-
dent television stations, and the advent and multiplication of home
video, satellite, and the Internet. “What has counted from the time
of Homer, Chaucer and Shakespeare to the present is the story and
the skill with which it is told, whatever the medium,” he observes.
Even so, Eisner aggressively led Disney to embrace the Internet.
Among Disney’s major assets are some of the most visited Web sites:
Disney.com for entertainment, ESPN.com for sports, and ABC.com
for news. By partnering first with Starwave, a leading technology
company, and then with Infoseek, one of the most popular Web
search engines, Disney also created the Go Network, an Internet
space that collects and offers content from all Disney units.

Magic and Mice

Eisner explains that many people in the early 1980s thought ani-
mation was dead, a lost art. Roy Disney disagreed and proved that
when done properly, animation was magic. And as Eisner says,
“magic is the essence of Disney.” Disney’s success in renewing ani-


The Fireside CEO 233

mation was the product of a two-part strategy. First, it successfully
rereleased the great classics in old and new venues—in theaters and
then on the Disney Channel and on home video. Second, Disney
bolstered its motion picture animation organization. That effort was
a splash, producing such phenomenal productions as Who Framed
Roger Rabbit?, The Little Mermaid, Beauty and the Beast, Aladdin,
The Lion King, and Pocahantas. These efforts continued through the
1990s with Tarzan, a smash hit which weighs in as the second most
successful animated film Disney ever released.
These blockbusters tower alongside such brand-name Disney
characters as Mickey Mouse and help define Disney as a family-
oriented company. That enables it to avoid dependency on the hit-
or-miss business orientation shackling many other studios. Film-
making is a high-ris kindustry: Millions can be invested in a film
with no assurance of any return. That is why most major movie
studios release a dozen or more films per year, betting that the hits
will offset the misses (a practice not unlike that of dot-com specu-
lators in the late 1990s and early 2000s).
Disney’s strategy for overcoming these industry conditions is to
concentrate on cost control and selectivity. Two applications follow.
First, Disney emphasizes its family-oriented brand identification.
This creates a special niche that largely liberates Disney from the
hit-or-miss strategy. Second, that emphasis also gives Disney an op-
erating edge in the live-action film (and television) business, allowing
successes such as Father of the Bride, The Hand That Rocks the
Cradle, and Sister Act (plus scores of others too numerous to men-
tion, but thin kof Toy Story, Armageddon, The Horse Whisperer, and
Good Will Hunting).
The television business is even tougher than the motion picture
business, but again, Disney leverages its animation strengths to over-
come industry challenges. The Disney Channel is a major vehicle
for animation and a major competitive advantage for Disney in the
television business, with subscriber increases generally outpacing
those at competitor channels. Even before it acquired ABC in 1995,
Disney placed numerous successful shows with the networks, in-
cluding Home Improvement, Golden Girls, and Empty Nest. It later
scored knockout points with the ABC hit Who Wants to Be a Mil-
lionaire?, which Eisner says “transcended being a mere television
show and has entered into the culture.”
If magic is the essence of Disney, Mickey Mouse is its manifes-
tation. Mickey’s prominence leads Eisner to explore the intriguing


234 In Managers We Trust

question, “Which came first, Mickey Mouse or the Disney com-
pany?” The answer is not easy. Of course the company came first as
a logical and chronological matter, but Mickey was the company’s
real launching pad. Eisner quotes Walt Disney as fondly repeating:
“Remember, this all started with a mouse.” And it continues with
that mouse, as Eisner describes how Disney pulled out all the stops
to stage a worldwide celebration of Mickey’s sixty-fifth birthday in
1992.
Among the toughest business challenges Eisner and Disney
faced in recent years was the development of Euro Disney. This am-
bitious theme-par kundertaking was years in the making. During
many of them, Eisner expressed high hopes and great optimism.
Then struggles ensued, delays slowed progress, and hopes were low-
ered. But with tenacity bolstered by a long-term vision, Eisner and
Disney pulled through and Euro Disney opened with success. Eis-
ner’s candor in admitting trouble and accounting for his own errors
is a sign of trustworthiness that no investor should ignore.

Managing in the Spotlight

Euro Disney got a lot of press, but so do most activities of a company
that is a piece of American cultural history. This unyielding spotlight
poses special management problems that Eisner describes with great
understatement and felicity. Disney takes the lumps for its mistakes
but gets praise when it deserves to. Under Eisner’s stewardship Dis-
ney regularly ranks among the best entertainment companies in the
world, one of the best-managed companies overall, and one of the
most profitable and financially stable entertainment companies. In
1991 Disney also joined the Dow, the only representative of the en-
tertainment industry in that barometer of American (and world) fi-
nancial health.
Eisner attributes these successes to his entire management team
as well as all Disney employees, whom he affectionately refers to as
the “cast of Disney.” The spirit Eisner conveys to the cast of this
family entertainment company resonates with civic virtue and
public-spiritedness. From generating research funding for AIDS at
the 20th Anniversary Celebration of Walt Disney World in 1991, to
furnishing financial sustenance to a downtown theater in Los An-
geles in 1997, to practicing sound environmental policies company-
wide, Disney is long on public values. Disney is a major supporter
of education through an effort that dramatizes the importance of


The Fireside CEO 235

teachers in society and responded generously to the upheaval re-
flected in the Los Angeles riots of 1992.
Eisner’s exorbitant stoc koptions remain controversial and a
sticky issue (as was his decision to hire talent tsar Mike Ovitz, who
lasted at Disney for 14 months but cost the company several hundred
million dollars in severance payments). These options warrant care-
ful scrutiny in his case, as with all managers. Eisner makes no bones
about his pay level, arguing that his performance at Disney justifies
it. Whether you agree is a judgment call. Some investors could rea-
sonably adjust their valuation of Disney on the basis of both the
awards and Eisner’s defense of them; the question is what his ac-
count tells you about whether you want to entrust your wealth to
him.

TRUS

The Coca-Cola Company remains one of the world’s premier cor-
porations.5 Three priorities guided Coke’s actions under its late
CEO, Roberto C. Goizueta: creating value, strengthening the com-
pany’s trademarks, and focusing on the long term. These priorities
pervade and define Coke, a $150 billion operation when Goizueta
died in 1997, up from a $4 billion operation when he became CEO
a little more than a decade earlier. The lively pages of Goizueta’s
passionate and clear writings, some cowritten with his former right-
hand man, Donald Keough, explain why.
Consider first a few of the benchmarks. In 1995 and 1996 Coca-
Cola led Fortune’s ranking of wealth creators. As of year end 1995
its market cap was $93 billion, an increase in shareowner wealth of
$38 billion over the prior year. As of year end 1996 that figure had
increased to $131 billion, adding another $38 billion. While in 1976
Coca-Cola was the twentieth best wealth creator among publicly
traded U.S.-based companies, by 1995 it was fourth and in 1996 it
was first.
In 1995 and 1996 the total return on Coca-Cola stoc kexceeded
40%, and during the preceding 15 years it produced an average com-
pound annual total return rate of 30% (counting reinvested divi-
dends). From 1980 through 1995 Coca-Cola’s share price grew at an
average annual compound rate of 24%, creating nearly $89 billion
in shareowner wealth, compared with increases of 12% in the Dow
and 11% in the S&P 500. The annualized total return from 1981


236 In Managers We Trust

through 1990, assuming reinvestment of dividends, was 37%, and
from 1986 through 1990, it was 34%.
Driving these spectacular results, Goizueta repeatedly empha-
sized, was growth in unit case volume. From 1985 through 1995, unit
case volume outside North America grew at an average annual com-
pound rate of 8.2%, while within the United States it grew at an
average annual compound rate of 4.2% (compared with 2.7% indus-
trywide). In 1996 Coca-Cola set another record, with worldwide unit
case volume up 8% and selling 13.7 billion unit cases. Sales of the
Coca-Cola brand itself grew by nearly 450 million unit cases (a 6%
increase over 1995), while Sprite grew by more than 138 million unit
cases (up 13%, its third consecutive year of double-digit growth).

Owner Orientation and Long-Term Thinking

Adding fuel to this unstoppable engine was Goizueta’s business phi-
losophy. Goizueta saw himself as the steward of shareholder capital,
always tying Coke’s activities to shareholder values. He said that
“solid unit case volume growth is the foundation for generating eco-
nomic profit, which, experience teaches us, is the key to increasing
the value of [our shareowners’ investment].”
Under Goizueta, Coke focused on its core businesses and
adopted a long-term time horizon. Through disciplined and patient
attention to building the Coke brand for the long term, Goizueta
also created another trademar kat Coke: a company with an un-
quenchable thirst for selling more product to more customers all
over the world.
Goizueta believed that “the best way to generate consistently
strong short-term results is to keep our attention riveted on the long-
term.” That long-term focus during the 1980s and 1990s meant build-
ing step by step a “global business machine capable of sustaining
strong, profitable growth” over the decades to come.

Branding

At the foundation of that global business is the Coke brand. It “not
only has universal appeal and accessibility, but also meets the fun-
damental, frequently recurring human need for refreshment.” To get
people to choose Coke to meet their daily liquid needs, building


The Fireside CEO 237

brand strength was the key. Brand strength was for Goizueta not
solely about delivering value to the marketplace, marketing research
results, or balance sheet impacts. Goizueta defined brand strength
in terms of its “ability to command a premium price in exchange for
the very real and obvious value it delivers in return.”
Managing brand strength need not be tricky, although enough
businesses have squeezed brand strength to the point where its
price-value relationship led to its rejection by the market. Coke did
not make that mistake under Goizueta’s leadership. Instead, it con-
tinually sought to find ways to add brand strength by differentiating
the products, “making them unique and distinctive.” For many years
Coke used the AAA approach to its brand strength: availability, af-
fordability, and acceptability of its products. That strategy worked
well, but Goizueta moved to the next level in 1995, to the PPP ap-
proach: pervasive penetration (rather than mere availability), price-
to-value ratios for customers (rather than mere affordability), and
preferred (to merely acceptable).

Financial Prudence

Another foundation of Coke’s enormous success was Goizueta’s
commitment to financial prudence, epitomized by his decision in
1994 to effect at Coke a “financial reformation.” Noting that Coke’s
historical financial prudence had ossified by the early 1980s—“effec-
tively trapping a live organism within the hard constrictions of its
own fossil shell”—and rejuvenated in the latter 1980s, Goizueta re-
stated that commitment.
Goizueta announced a new way of measuring Coke’s perfor-
mance. Economic profits (a version of what would later be called
economic value added), not just growth in revenues or earnings,
became the yardstick. Economic profit is “net operating profit after
taxes, less a charge for the average cost of capital employed to pro-
duce that profit.”
Evaluating businesses with this measure led Coke to divest some
poorly performing operations and renewed the focus on the core
business of soft drin kconcentrate (with some holdings in bottlers
complemented by an economically profitable foods business).
Coke used debt sparingly to enhance shareholder returns and
effected share repurchases to enhance earnings per share. It lowered
its dividend payout ratio while increasing the annual dividend to free

238 In Managers We Trust

up cash for reinvestment at low cost. It reinvested those and other
funds to expand its global bottling networ kto erect an extensive and
efficient business system. All this Goizueta explained with great clar-
ity to his fellow shareholders.

Infrastructure Fortification

Part of that investment helped finance improvements in its bottlers’
processing and distribution systems. Not only did those investments
bolster current and future product sales (and strengthen the Coke-
bottler partnership), Coke could subsequently sell its interest in the
investment at an additional profit for its shareholders.
Goizueta called Coke’s investment in and development of an ex-
tensive and efficient bottling and distribution system “infrastructure
fortification.” It entailed continued and deeper investments in the
system that bottles and distributes Coca-Cola products. A variety of
means were used to fortify the system, from encouraging bottlers to
reinvest to investing equity directly and supplying managerial exper-
tise.
Through these practices, Coke expanded around the globe to
nearly two-hundred countries to create billions of new potential cus-
tomers. Between 1980 and 1994 the number of potential Coke cus-
tomers more than doubled. With sales volume growth as the key to
sustaining value growth, this shows why Coke’s average return on
capital was over triple the approximate cost of that capital.
Adding strength to Coke’s focus on the core brands in its global
business system was geographic diversification. Coke enjoys a
strong—maybe dominant—position in blue chip markets such as the
United States, Germany, and Japan. It is committed to dominating
new worlds of opportunity such as eastern Europe and Indonesia.
Add to that the “start-up” markets of China and India and you have
overall diversity through which to “use existing strengths to create
future strengths.” (That fortification is one of the reasons Coke pre-
vailed against the adversity of the Asian financial crisis of 1998.)

Resource Allocation

In Coke’s global business environment, Goizueta said, his primary
challenge was to optimally allocate resources generated in developed
markets to invest in less developed ones. The greatest growth poten-
tial for Coke in the world, Goizueta told a group of students in 1995,


The Fireside CEO 239

was in southern California! Coke sold more cans and bottles of Coke
per capita in Hungary than in southern California, making the latter
the more “emerging” of the two markets.
Financial reformation, infrastructure fortification, and geo-
graphic expansion were meant to create the “best machine possible.”
A complementary initiative would “equip that machine with a
uniquely powerful growth engine.” This was the consumer marketing
effort designed to drive world demand for the brand. It called for
Coke to market its products as distinctive—“different, better and
special”—relentlessly deepening brand power.
Goizueta ignored the varied views from the sidelines that ranged
from those who said Coke already was a premier consumer market-
ing outfit and could do no more to those who said there were plenty
of other great companies that hold that title. Noting that the average
human body needs at least 64 ounces of liquid daily to survive, Goi-
zueta saw Coke as having a huge window of opportunity.
Goizueta sought to promote the brand everywhere in the world,
driving dramatic growth in already developed markets such as the
United States, Japan, and Europe. To deepen brand strength verti-
cally—that is, in existing strong markets as compared to horizontal
building in new ones—required exploiting Goizueta’s commitment
to product differentiation. Goizueta said that if the keys to selling
real estate are location, location, location, the “keys to selling con-
sumer products are differentiation, differentiation, differentiation.”
Many were astonished in 1996 when Coke did what they thought
was impossible: It surpassed the combined consumption of the two
leading teas in the United Kingdom and that of the leading bottled
water in France!

Learning Culture

These insights guided Coke instinctively for years. Goizueta set them
out in writing as part of an effort to create throughout the company
a “learning culture” in which these principles were institutionalized.
Like GE’s Welch, he sought to learn from every participant in Coke’s
business: consumers, customers, partners, competitors, and even un-
related organizations. For example, another reality at Goizueta’s
Coke was his team’s ability to find opportunities others could not
see. His people search the world not to see where Coke already is
but to see where it is not.
Goizueta helped create another extraordinary reality: Coca-Cola


240 In Managers We Trust

adds value “to everyone who touches it.” Shareholders, bottlers,
Coke’s customers, and end consumers all benefit from Coke. Goi-
zueta emphasized particularly Coke’s relationships with its bottlers.
Throughout the world, a once-fragmented group of bottlers increas-
ingly consolidated on a country-by-country basis—in Japan, Ger-
many, and elsewhere—to gain substantial competitive advantages. As
for the customers, many restaurants must sell three hamburgers to
make the same profit they make from selling a large Coke. Coke
went out of its way to let its customers know this.

Conquering Economic Adversity

Concentrating on the long term by emphasizing short-term prudence
is how Coke and Goizueta conquered the economic adversity of the
early 1990s. Coke deployed its resources amid global economic mal-
aise to cope with the slowdown through strategic pricing and cost
controls. It deployed those resources to capitalize on those condi-
tions by making flexible marketing investments. In this two-front
campaign Goizueta never wavered from his conviction, shared by
Keough and Coke’s other top managers, that a hybrid perspective is
optimal: What distinguished Coke was its simultaneous “constancy
of purpose” and its “continuous discontentment with the immediate
present.”
That hybrid perspective was doubly valuable in facing adversity
and proved the adage that tough times make the strong stronger.
The aggressive investment in the long-term growth and value of the
business, in good times as well as in bad, is what’s behind Fortune
magazine’s regular ranking of Coke as one of the most admired com-
panies in America, especially for its long-term investment value.
Goizueta’s long-term orientation gave succor in bad times, as did
his unwillingness to waste energy on forecasting the economic fu-
ture. It is not possible to control external events such as “global
economic trends, currency fluctuations and devaluations, natural
disasters, political upheavals, social unrest, bad weather or schizo-
phrenic stoc kmarkets,” but Goizueta notes that he and every other
manager has complete control over his or her own behavior.
Managers cannot allow themselves to be distracted by the exter-
nal environment. What they can and should do is focus the man-
agement team on what it can control: resource deployment to build
a foundation for future growth, whatever the current economic cli-
mate. The future, in those terms, is in no way preordained but in-



The Fireside CEO 241

stead is “an infinite series of openings, of possibilities.” He empha-
sized that what uncertainty calls for, especially in difficult economic
environments, is what the Greeks called practical intelligence. This
world view “forces adaptability and teaches constant preparedness.”

Pragmatism

Practical intelligence also “acknowledges that nothing quite suc-
ceeds as planned” and that what is crucial is “pragmatic adaptability”
to what is new. And new always comes—change is inevitable. The
sharp business focus at Coke is what best prepared the company to
meet change. Indeed, as Goizueta suggested, few large companies
are as focused as Coke or as “tightly riveted” to a particular business
as Coke is to soft drinks.
Animating Goizueta’s letters was an overarching dominant
theme: The company’s shareholders own it. All other themes—build-
ing brand strength through the AAAs or PPPs, differentiating the
brand as special and better, fiscal prudence, and focus—serve the
ultimate principle that the investors are the owners.
Success at Coke, Goizueta emphasized to all the troops, was
“creating value for the people who have entrusted their assets to us.”
That is the reason why the company (and any other business) exists.
All the other social benefits Coke or any other company generates
by “serving customers and consumers, creating jobs, positively im-
pacting society, supporting communities—happen only as long as we
fulfill our mission of creating value for [shareholders],” Goizueta
said.

Shortly before his death Goizueta quoted for his management
team the words of the German poet and playwright Goethe: “What-
ever you can do or dream you can, begin it. Boldness has genius,
power and magic in it. Begin it now.”
Goizueta believed that boldness sustains growth. He expressed
gratitude to all the participants in the Coke venture—associates,
customers, bottling partners, board members, and most of all, he
said, his fellow shareowners—for their trust and confidence in his
team’s ability to create value.
Well-earned trust indeed, and indispensable when markets, num-
bers, and governance tell only part of the story in business analysis.


CONCLUSION:
THE V CULTURE

eaders with an arbitrage orientation may regret that the exem-
plars of great modern CEOs covered in the last chapter, apart
R
from Warren Buffett, consist of one who is dead, one who has an-
nounced his retirement, and only one who is likely to reign for the
foreseeable future. Who’s next, and why not name them?
If I knew, I would not say. Not so much because I want to gain
a competitive edge. No, my reticence is precisely because of an in-
sight in this book: Judgment is the key, and my judgment will invar-
iably differ from yours. Our circles of competence are necessarily
different. Our interpretation of the past differs, and our prognosis
for the future must as well. It contradicts the whole point of this
boo kfor me to tell you who I believe are the up-and-coming star
CEOs. My picks are irrelevant to your judgments.
Go bac kto the masters mentioned in Chapter 1 and you’ll see
that it was precisely their independence of thought, their utter and
profound common sense, which led to their remarkable success. I
condense these ideas and insights in the spirit of a teacher and pro-
fessor, not an investment adviser. I hope you’ll use these pages as a
foundation for picking stocks as a savvy, sophisticated investor (or,
failing that, picking advisers who share respect for the basic philos-
ophy of outstanding investors such as Graham and Buffett).
The basic philosophy of business analysis investing integrates
three branches: finance, accounting, and governance. Finance is
commonly defined as “the science of management of money and
other assets.” So much for this definition, if you agree that finance
is one part science and the other part art. Behavioral economics, a
field that draws on numerous disciplines, including psychology, sta-
tistics, history, and sociology, may deserve to be called a social sci-

243

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


244 In Managers We Trust

ence. Its approach to finance is the most promising, for it recognizes
the first branch of intelligent investing: Graham’s foundational in-
sight that price and value are different things.
The meaning and measure of value are the second branch, pur-
suits requiring a grasp of basic ideas from the world of accounting.
Accounting has long been known as the language of business, and
the discretion managers have in applying accounting principles re-
quires intelligent investors to become translators of that language.
When that discretion is abused, it is safer to side with those who
declare accounting a state of mind rather than an art or science.
Fluency in accounting gives you a huge investment edge, and even
conversational accounting will put you at the top of the investing
class.
Since market prices and accounting numbers are both fragile
grounds for firm and final investment decisions, the third branch is
managerial trustworthiness. Formal and overly general governance
principles don’t help very much here. What you need are people you
are happy to entrust your wealth with. Identifying them is all art.
In the stoc kmarket forest, loo kfor these three branches. They
enable you to steer away from the Q culture and thrive in the V
culture, a value-oriented investing culture nurtured by Graham and
Buffett.


NOTES

Chapter 1

1. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 108.

2. Fred Schwed, Jr., Where Are the Customers’ Yachts? (1st ed. 1940; rev. ed. John
Wiley & Sons, 1995), 6–7.

3. The New York Stock Exchange Fact Book (New York, 1999), http://
www.nyse.com; Gretchen Morgenson, “Investing’s Longtime Best Bet Is Being
Trampled by the Bulls,” The New York Times, January 15, 2000.

4. Report of the Presidential Tas kForce on Market Mechanisms (the Brady Re-
port), 1988.

5. Greg Ip, “Market on a High Wire,” The Wall Street Journal, January 18, 2000.

6. Burton G. Malkiel, A Random Walk Down Wall Street (1st ed. 1973; 7th rev.
ed. W. W. Norton, 1999), 57–61.

7. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 72.

8. Robert J. Shiller, Irrational Exuberance (Princeton University Press, 2000), 118–
132, catalogs and evaluates the 25 top bursts and busts on global stoc kex-
changes during one- and five-year periods from the 1960s through the 1990s.

9. Joseph de la Vega, Confusio'n de Confusiones (1st ed. 1688; rev. ed. John Wiley
& Sons, 1996), 159–165 (the selected quotation condenses original material
without indicating omissions).

10. Malkiel, Random Walk, 185.

11. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 63, 84. The price per share was $5.63, ag-
gregating $100 million, compared to a value of $400 to $500 million.

12. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 289 (footnote omitted).

Chapter 2

1. For additional analysis and sources, consult Lawrence A. Cunningham, “From
Random Walks to Chaotic Crashes: The Linear Genealogy of the Efficient
Capital Market Hypothesis,” The George Washington University Law Review,
vol. 62 (1994), on which this chapter is based.

245

Copyright 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click Here for Terms of Use


246 Notes

2. Louis Bachelier, “Theory of Speculation,” reprinted in The Random Character
of Stock Market Prices, Paul H. Cootner, ed. (rev. ed. MIT Press, 1964).

3. Eugene F. Fama, “The Behavior of Stoc kMarket Prices,” Journal of Business ,
vol. 38 (1965).

4. Sidney S. Alexander, “Price Movements in Speculative Markets: Trends or Ran-
dom Walks?” Industry Management Review, May 1961.

5. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 133.

6. Paul A. Samuelson, “Proof That Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Ran-
domly,” Industry Management Review, Spring 1965.

7. Milton Friedman, “The Methodology of Positive Economics,” in Essays in Pos-
itive Economics (University of Chicago Press, 1953).

8. Andrew Lo and A. Craig MacKinlay, A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street
(Princeton University Press, 1999).

9. Eugene A. Fama, “Efficient Capital Markets: II,” Journal of Finance , vol. 46
(1991).

10. James Tobin, “On the Efficiency of the Financial System,” Lloyds Bank Review,
July 1984.

11. William F. Sharpe, Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets (McGraw-Hill, 1970);
Kenneth J. Arrow, “Ris kPerception in Psychology and Economics,” Economic
Inquiry, vol. 20 (1982).

12. Lawrence H. Summers, “Does the Stoc kMarket Rationally Reflect Fundamen-
tal Values?” Journal of Finance , vol. 41 (1986).

13. Fischer Black, “Noise,” Journal of Finance , vol. 41 (1986).

14. Andrei Shleifer, Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance (Ox-
ford University Press, 2000).

15. Harry M. Markowitz, Portfolio Diversification: Efficient Diversification of In-
vestments (John Wiley & Sons, 1959).

16. Sharpe, Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets.

17. Andrei Shleifer, “Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down?” Journal of Fi-
nance, vol. 41 (1986).

18. Francis Fukuyama, Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity (Free
Press, 1995).

19. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 61, n. 2.

20. Lawrence A. Cunningham, ed., “Conversations from the Buffett Symposium,”
Cardozo Law Review, vol. 19 (Sept.–Nov. 1997), 812.

Chapter 3

1. For additional analysis and sources, consult Lawrence A. Cunningham, “From
Random Walks to Chaotic Crashes: The Linear Genealogy of the Efficient
Capital Market Hypothesis,” The George Washington University Law Review,
vol. 62 (1994), on which this chapter is based.


Notes 247

2. H. E. Hurst, “Long-Term Storage Capacities of Reservoirs,” Transactions of the
American Society of Civil Engineers, vol. 116 (1951).

3. Edgar E. Peters, Chaos and Order in the Capital Markets (John Wiley & Sons,
1991); Edgar E. Peters, Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to In-
vestment and Economics (John Wiley & Sons, 1994).

4. Henri Poincare', Science and Method (1st ed. 1908; rev. ed. Dover Press, 1952).

5. Edward Lorenz, “Deterministic Nonperiodic Flow,”Journal of Atmospheric Sci-
ences, vol. 20 (1963); Edward Lorenz, Nonlinear Dynamical Economics and
Chaotic Motion (Springer-Verlag, 1989).

6. Alan Wolf, “Chaos in the Stadium,” Algorithm, April 1992.

7. These figures were prepared by Alan Wolf.

8. Alan Wolf, et al., “Determining Lyapunov Exponents from Time Series,” Phys-
ica, vol. 16D (1985).

9. Benoit B. Mandelbrot, The Fractal Geometry of Nature (W. H. Freeman, 1988);
Benoit B. Mandelbrot, ed., Fractals and Scaling in Finance: Discontinuity, Con-
centration, Risk (Springer-Verlag, 1997).

10. Andrei Shleifer, Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance (Ox-
ford University Press, 2000), 121–22.

11. John Y. Campbell and Robert J. Shiller, “The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expec-
tations of Future Dividends and Discount Factors,” Review of Financial Studies,
vol. 1 (1998); John Y. Campbell and John Ammer, “What Moves Stoc kand Bond
Markets: A Variance Decomposition for Long-Term Asset Returns,” Journal of
Finance, vol. 48 (1993).

12. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 72.

13. Warren E. Buffett, “The Superinvestors of Graham and Doddsville,” Hermes
(Columbia Business School), Fall 1984.

14. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st. ed. 1949; rev. ed Harper & Row,
1973), 36–37.

15. Ibid.

Chapter 4

1. Alex Berenson, “On Hair-Trigger Wall Street, A Stoc kPlunges on Fake News,”
The New York Times, August 26, 2000.

2. Susan E. Hurd and Jonathan M. Winer, “On-Line Securities Fraud Under Scru-
tiny,” The New York Law Journal, February 22, 2000.

3. Professor Howard M. Friedman of the University of Toledo Law School fur-
nished testimony providing some of these examples before the Permanent In-
vestigations Subcommittee of the Senate Governmental Affairs Committee on
March 22, 1999.

4. SEC v. Francis Tribble &Sloane Fitzgerald, SEC Litigation Release No. 15959,
October 27, 1998.

248 Notes

5. SEC v. Remington-Hall Capital Corp. &Douglas T. Fonteno, SEC Litigation
Release No. 15943, October 22, 1998.

6. Alex Berenson, “Two Accused of Using E-Mail to Commit Stoc kFraud,” The
New York Times, February 25, 2000.

7. Jeffrey Keegan, “Regulators Step Up Fight against Internet Fraud,” Investment
Dealers Digest, August 7, 1998.

8. Philip L. Carret, The Art of Speculation (1st ed. 1930; rev. ed. Fraser, 1984).

9. Edwin LeFe`vre, Reminiscences of a Stock Operator (1st ed. 1923; rev. ed. John
Wiley & Sons, 1994).

10. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 142.

11. Leslie Eaton, “Internet Investing: Spotlight on Risk,” International Herald Trib-
une, December 6, 1996.

12. SEC v. Aziz-Golshani, No. 99–13139 (CBM) (Federal Central District of Cali-
fornia, December 15, 1999); Rebecca Buckman and Michael Schroeder, “Web
Postings Draw Charges of Stoc kFraud,” The Wall Street Journal, December 16,
1999; Gretchen Morgenson, “Internet’s Role Is Implicated in Stoc kFraud,” The
New York Times, December 16, 1999.

13. SEC Litigation Release No. 16399 (January 5, 2000) (reporting on SEC v. Yun
Soo Oh Park, Federal Northern District of Illinois, Case No. 00C 0049); Jen-
nifer Friedlin, “The SEC Files Civil Fraud Charges against Tokyo Joe,” The-
Street.com & NYTimes.com, January 2000; John C. Coffee, Jr., “Tokyo Joe and
the First Amendment,” The New York Law Journal, January 20, 2000.

14. “Net Damage: PairGain Hoax Revealed,” Investor Relations Business, April 26,
1999; Associated Press, “PairGain Worker Sentenced in Fraud Case,” The New
York Times, August 31, 1999.

15. Alex Berenson, “S.E.C. Reaches Settlement in Web-Based ‘Pump and Dump’
Case,” The New York Times, March 3, 2000; Michael Schroeder, “Georgetown
Students Draw Web Investors—and an SEC Bust,” The Wall Street Journal,
March 3, 2000.

16. William M. Bulkeley, “Presste kSuit Alleges Short Sellers Posted False State-
ments On-Line,” The Wall Street Journal, September 18, 1997.

17. Gretchen Morgenson, “S.E.C. Says Teenager Had After-School Hobby: Online
Stoc kFraud,” The New York Times, September 21, 2000.

18. Lawrence Harris, “Volatility, Portfolio Insurance, and the Role of Specialists
and Market Makers,” Cornell Law Review, vol. 74 (1989), provided part of the
foundation for the following discussion.

19. Michael Schroeder and Randall Smith, “Sweeping Changes in Market Struc-
ture Sought: Major Firms Propose Central Order System and Single Regulator,”
The Wall Street Journal, February 29, 2000; Alex Berenson, “Top Wall St. Ex-
ecutives Urge Trading Overhaul,” The New York Times, March 1, 2000.

20. Michael Schroeder, “NASD, NYSE Discussed Merging to Keep Up With Mar-
ket Changes,” The Wall Street Journal, March 3, 2000; Greg Ip and Randall


Notes 249

Smith, “Instinet, Date kRecently Held Merger Talks,” The Wall Street Journal,
March 3, 2000.

21. Thomas Kalinke, “Sleepless in New York: Evening Hours at the Exchange,”
Financial History, vol. 69 (Spring 2000).

22. Rebecca Buckman, “Heavy Losses: The Rise and Collapse of a Day Trader,”
The Wall Street Journal, February 28, 2000.

23. Senate Governmental Affairs Committee, Permanent Subcommittee on Inves-
tigations, February 25, 2000; Bloomberg News, “Day Trading’s Risks and Pres-
sures Are Described to a Senate Panel,” The New York Times, February 25,
2000.

24. Gerald M. Loeb, The Battle for Investment Survival (1st ed. 1935; rev. ed. John
Wiley & Sons, 1996).

25. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffet:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 90.

26. Edward Wyatt, “Day Traders Are Formidable Market Force,” The New York
Times, April 14, 1999.

27. The Charles Schwab Corporation, 1999 Annual Report, 41–42; Patric kMc-
Geehan, “Profit Up at Citigroup, Merrill and Schwab,” The New York Times,
April 18, 2000.

28. Patric kMcGeehan, “The Unmutual Fund,” The New York Times, May 18, 2000.

Chapter 5

1. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 110.

2. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 120, 122, 134.

3. Ibid., 110.

4. John C. Bogle, Common Sense on Mutual Funds (John Wiley & Sons, 1999).

5. Gerald M. Loeb, The Battle for Investment Survival (1st ed. 1935; rev. ed. John
Wiley & Sons, 1996).

6. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 79; Graham, Intelligent Investor, 54, 282–
283.

7. Gretchen Morgenson, “Buying on Margin Becomes a Habit,” The New York
Times, March 24, 2000.

8. Gretchen Morgenson, “Stock-Trading Cheerleader Now Faces $45 Million
Debt,” The New York Times, April 19, 2000.

9. Nic kLeeson, Rogue Trader (Warner, 1997).

10. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 228–231.

11. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 57.

12. Charles T. Munger, “A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates
to Investment Management and Business,” Outstanding Investor Digest, vol. X
(May 5, 1995).


250 Notes

13. Edwin LeFe`vre, Reminiscences of a Stock Operator (1st ed. 1923; rev. ed. John
Wiley & Sons, 1994).

14. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 245.

15. Ibid., 124–125

16. Bill Spindle, “Been There? Euphoric ’80s in Japan Ended in Long Slide,” The
Wall Street Journal, January 18, 2000.

17. Steve Liesman and Jacob M. Schlesinger, “Blunted Spike: The Price of Oil Has
Doubled This Year; So, Where’s the Recession?” The Wall Street Journal, De-
cember 15, 1999; Joseph Kahn, “Surge in Oil Prices Is Raising Specter of In-
flation Spike,” The New York Times, February 21, 2000.

18. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 162.

19. Gretchen Morgenson, “Investing’s Longtime Best Bet Is Being Trampled by the
Bulls,” The New York Times, January 15, 2000.

Chapter 6

1. Donald Schwartz, late professor at the Georgetown University Law Center,
prepared the original version of this parable, rewritten for publication here and
previously appearing in others forms in Lawrence A. Cunningham, Introductory
Accounting and Finance for Lawyers (West Group 2d ed., 1999) and Lewis D.
Solomon, et al., Corporations Law and Policy (West Group 4th ed., 1998).

2. Carol Loomis, “Mr. Buffett on the Stoc kMarket,” Fortune, November 22, 1999.

3. Charles T. Munger, author of “A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It
Relates to Investment Management and Business,” Outstanding Investor Digest,
vol. X (May 5, 1995), furnished this example.

4. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 71.

Chapter 7

1. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 63.

2. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 92–93.

3. Benjamin Graham, The Interpretation of Financial Statements (1st ed. 1937; rev.
ed. Harper Business, 1998), 77.

4. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 208.

5. Ibid., 91–92.

6. Adrian J. Slywotzky and David J. Morrison, authors of Profit Patterns (Times
Business, 1999), identify and discuss the patterns described in the accompa-
nying text.

7. Bill Miller, “Amazon.com’s Allure,” Barron’s, November 15, 1999.

8. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 96–97.


Notes 251

9. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 286.

10. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 99.

11. The psychology literature calls the resistance bias a “principle of conservatism”
and the pattern-seeking bias a “representativeness heuristic.” Both labels seem
not only unwieldy but imprecise when adapted for thinking about investor be-
havior. Nevertheless, investment theorists cling to these terms in arguing that
these cognitive biases play a role in explaining market inefficiencies. For an
example, consider Andrei Shleifer, Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Be-
havioral Finance (Oxford University Press, 2000).

12. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 87.

13. Ibid., 53.

Chapter 8

1. Leopold A. Bernstein and John J. Wild, Analysis of Financial Statements (5th
ed. McGraw-Hill, 2000), 102–03.

2. Benjamin Graham, The Interpretation of Financial Statements (1st ed. 1937; rev.
ed. Harper Business, 1998), 32.

3. For more, consult ibid. or Lawrence A. Cunningham, Introductory Accounting
and Finance for Lawyers (2nd ed. West Group, 1999), on which this and the
next chapter draw (the title is intended to show that it is for the nonaccountant;
it is not exclusively for lawyers).

Chapter 9

1. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 277.

2. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 101. Note also
Subrata N. Chakravarty, “Three Little Words,” Forbes, April 6, 1998.

3. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 187.

4. The per share figures throughout this chapter do not take into account any
stoc ksplits occurring in 2000 or beyond.

5. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 14–15.

6. Michael Metz and David Kerdell, “Graham and Dodd Revisited,” Portfolio Strat-
egy (CIBC Oppenheimer, December 11, 1998).

7. Benjamin Graham, The Interpretation of Financial Statements (1st ed. 1937; rev.
ed. Harper Business, 1998), 15, 23.

8. Ibid., 49.

9. Ibid., 48–49.

10. Philip L. Carret, The Art of Speculation (1st ed. 1930; rev. ed. Fraser, 1984).

11. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 277–282.


252 Notes

12. John Burr Williams, The Theory of Investment Value (1st ed. 1938; rev. ed. Fra-
ser, 1997).

13. Robert Shiller, Irrational Exuberance (Princeton University Press, 2000) (not-
ing the studies referred to and reporting on others done directly that show
slightly lower expected returns), 52–55; Graham, Intelligent Investor, 122.

14. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 85.

15. Stern Stewart, the firm that trademarked the term “economic value added,”
publishes volumes of material on the concept, including G. Bennett Stewart
III, “EVA : Fact and Fantasy,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance , vol. 7
(1994).

16. The Coca-Cola Company defines “economic value added” in a glossary in its
annual report as year-to-year growth in after-tax operating income in excess of
a varying estimated charge for average operating capital employed.

17. Graham, Interpretation, 75–76.

Chapter 10

1. David Burgstahler and Ilia Dichev, “Earnings Management to Avoid Earnings
Decreases and Losses,” Journal of Accounting and Economics , vol. 24 (1997).

2. Michael Schroeder, “SEC to Adopt Disclosure Rules for Companies,” The Wall
Street Journal, December 16, 1999.

3. New York Stock Exchange Listed Company Manual, Section 303.01, Audit Com-
mittees (available from http://www.nyse.com/listed). Big accounting firms used
these rules and recommendations to formulate statements of audit committee
standards. For example, see PriceWaterhouseCoopers, Audit Committees: Best
Practices for Protecting Shareholder Interests (1999); KMPG, Shaping the Audit
Committee Agenda (1999).

4. Graham’s lampooning appears in Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cun-
ningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett: Lessons For Corporate America (The
Cunningham Group, 1997), 159–65. Briloff’s wor kincludes More Debits Than
Credits (Harper & Row, 1976) and Unaccountable Accounting (Harper & Row,
1972).

5. Some of these charade discussions are adapted from Lawrence A. Cunningham,
Introductory Accounting and Finance for Lawyers (2nd ed. West Group, 1999).

6. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 193.

7. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 167.

Chapter 11

1. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper &
Row, 1973), 155.

2. Ibid., 286.

3. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:


Notes 253

Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 147.

4. For additional analysis and sources, consult Lawrence A. Cunningham, “Com-
monalities and Prescriptions in the Vertical Dimension of Global Corporate
Governance,” Cornell Law Review, vol. 84 (1999), on which this and the fol-
lowing chapters draw.

5. Graham, Intelligent Investor, 270.

6. AMP, Inc. v. Allied-Signal, Inc ., 1998 US District LEXIS 15617 (Federal Eastern
District of Pennsylvania, October 8, 1998), reversed on other grounds by the
Federal Third Circuit Court of Appeals, 168 Federal Reporter 3d 649 (January
20, 1999).

7. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 47.

Chapter 12

1. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 138.

2. Ibid., 86–87, 96.

3. Roberta Romano, “Corporate Law and Corporate Governance,” Industrial and
Corporate Change, vol. 5 (1996); Sanjai Bhagat and Bernard Black, “The Un-
certain Relationship between Board Composition and Firm Performance,” Busi-
ness Lawyer, vol. 54 (1999).

4. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 40.

5. James A. Brickley, Jeffrey L. Coles, and Gregg Jarrell, “Leadership Structure:
Separating the CEO and Chairman of the Board,”Journal of Corporate Finance ,
vol. 3 (1997).

6. Ira M. Millstein and Paul W. MacAvoy, “The Active Board of Directors and
Performance of the Large Publicly Traded Corporation,” Columbia University
Law Review, vol. 98 (1998).

7. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 47–54.

8. Investors Responsibility Research Center (press release), “Investors, CEOs,
Split on Best Governance Practices for Dot-Com Companies,” January 26,
2000.

9. SEC Rule 14a-8 under the Federal Securities Exchange Act of 1934.

10. Benjamin Graham, The Memoirs of the Dean of Wall Street (McGraw-Hill, 1996;
posthumous publication, Seymour Chatman, ed.), 201–212. The company was
Northern Pipeline, and the year was 1928 (Graham was 34 years old). Ibid.,
320.

11. Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor (1st ed. 1949; 4th rev. ed. Harper
and Row, 1973), 270.

Chapter 13

1. Joseph Kahn, “AMP Rejects Allied Signal’s Takeover Bid of $10 Billion,” The
New York Times, August 22, 1998.


254 Notes

2. John A. Byrnes, “The Blame When the Boss Fails,” Business Week, December
27, 1999.

3. Consult Kevin Murphy, “Corporate Performance and Managerial Remunera-
tion: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Accounting and Economics , vol. 7
(1985), and Hamid Mehran, “Executive Compensation Structure, Ownership,
and Firm Performance,” Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 38 (1995).

4. Ben & Jerry’s Homemade, Inc., 1992 Annual Report (5:1 ratio raised in 1990 to
7:1); Ben & Jerry’s Homemade, Inc., 1998 Annual Report (16:1 ratio at its “his-
torical high” and would be higher if “the present value of unexercised stoc
options were included”).

5. Lee Gomes, “McAfee.com to Make Long-Awaited IPO,” The Wall Street Jour-
nal, December 2, 1999.

6. Haig Simonian and Ni i Tait, “U.S. Executives Earn Much More,” The Fi-
nancial Times (London), August 3, 1998.

7. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren Buffett:
Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 54–55.

8. “Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation,” Statement of Financial Account-
ing Standards No. 123 (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1995).

9. Gretchen Morgenson, “Investors May Now Eye Costs of Stoc kOptions,” The
New York Times, August 29, 2000 (reporting studies performed by Pat Mc-
Connell of Bear Stearns); Manitou Investment Management Ltd., The Long
View: The Amazing Stock Option Bubble (October 1999) (reporting studies per-
formed by the British research firm Smithers and the U.S. investment banking
firm Sanford Bernstein).

10. David Leonhardt, “In the Options Age, Rising Pay (and Risk): Will Today’s
Huge Rewards Devour Tomorrow’s Earnings?” The New York Times, April 2,
2000.

11. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 58.

12. Reuters, “Study Says Mergers Often Don’t Aid Investors,” The New York Times,
December 1, 1999.

13. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 143.

14. Mattell, Inc., SEC Form 8-K (filed July 22, 1999).

15. Mattell, Inc., SEC Form 8-K (filed October 22, 1999).

16. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 123–127.

17. Beginning in 1999, the author helped direct a project on firm structures for the
Independence Standards Board, and his views expressed here do not necessarily
represent those of that project or of the board.

18. Buffett and Cunningham, Essays, 168.

Chapter 14

1. David Gladstone, Venture Capital Handbook (Prentice-Hall, 1988), 101–104.
2. Warren E. Buffett and Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Essays of Warren
Buffett: Lessons for Corporate America (The Cunningham Group, 1997), 36


Notes 255

(this is one of Berkshire Hathaway’s famous “Owner Related Business Prin-
ciples”).

3. This discussion draws on the annual letters of John F. (Jack) Welch to General
Electric Co. shareholders from 1985 through 2000. Some of them were coau-
thored with other GE executives.

4. This discussion draws on the annual letters of Michael D. (Mike) Eisner to
Walt Disney Co. shareholders from 1988 through 2000.

5. This discussion draws on the annual letters of Roberto C. Goizueta to Coca-
Cola Co. shareholders from 1985 through 1996, plus an article enclosed with
one of them by Mr. Goizveta called “The Emerging Post-Conglomerate Era:
Changing the Shape of Corporate America,” Leaders, April–June 1989.


‘This timely boo kchallenges investors to move away from the recently-
popular ‘Q Culture’ of speculation to the ‘V Culture’ of value investing,
based on business analysis that focuses on the basics of finance, account-
ing, and governance. The author reminds us that, ‘earnings and cash
flows are what give a business value’—the eternal message of long-run
success in equity investing. It is the critical lin kin the investment chain,
and Larry Cunningham’s boo kforges it with heat, power, and persuasive-
ness.’’
Jac kBogle, Founder and Former Chairman,
The Vanguard Group

‘‘Larry Cunningham masterfully tackles critical subjects at the heart of
today’s markets. A much-needed wor kon a unique style of investing, this
boo kputs the ABCs of common sense valuation bac kinto the business of
investing. This is the place to loo kfor insight and guidance in the age of
volatile markets and colliding ideas.’’
Alan C. (‘‘Ace’’) Greenberg, Chairman, Bear Stearns

‘‘Anyone desiring to be a successful investor should read this excellent
boo kpresenting the important investing principles of Graham, Buffett,
Fisher, and others in a most insightful and understandable manner.’’
David J. (‘‘Sandy’’) Gottesman, Chairman, First Manhattan

‘‘Remarkably timely. For stoc kplayers who realize they played the greatest
fool in the Internet stoc kgame, Cunningham offers a tool for rehabilita-
tion: a guide to thoughtful investing. For earnest investors, he shows how
to live profitably with the moodiness of Mr. Market.’’
David Henry, Associate Editor, Finance, Business Week

‘‘While the stoc kmarket does not always behave rationally, Larry Cun-
ningham’s well-articulated and insightful views as to value investing are a
refreshing reminder that, just as night follows day, a return to the princi-
ples at the core of Cunningham’s commonsense approach to investing is
inevitable.’’
Samuel J. Heyman, Chairman of the Board and CEO,
GAF Corporation

‘‘Puzzled by acronyms, buzz words, the pop investing concepts? Cunning-
ham explains then debunks them. He gets down to the fundamentals that
investors must know about companies in order to choose reliable winners
in the stoc kmarket.’’
Janet Lowe, Author, Benjamin Graham on
Value Investing and Warren Buffett Speaks